Lessons and questions from Google Android- Part 1 – the market definition

Two Androids

On the 19th of September the Google decision was finally made public after a long waiting period, which in hindsight may seem less surprising given its length (327 pages!) and extensive scope of analysis. As in the case of Microsoft, the decision provides us with lots of material for discussion. The decision covers the market definition as well as the analysis of abuses in the context of two (and multi) sided markets and potentially the matter of extraterritorial application of EU competition law. This post looks into some of the issues concerning the market definition. The remainder of the issues will be addressed soon in a follow-up post.

Market definition

The market definition in the Android decision is undoubtedly one of the most disputed aspects of the case, which is not surprising as any abuse of dominance case depends on the outcome of the market definition for the purpose of establishing dominance. However, while market definitions are often disputed in practice, the market definition in the Android case constitutes somewhat of a novelty, as it involves (at least two) multi-sided platforms: namely the Android OS and the Google Play Store. Accordingly, when defining the relevant market under such circumstances it is not only about determining the scope of the relevant market but also about determining how many markets need to be defined. As discussed on multiple occasions, this is due to the fact that the multi-sided platforms facilitate the interaction between two or more separate customer groups that display an (inter)dependency of demand with regard to each other and the platform. Such interdependency is a result of the indirect network effects that are often in play in the case of platforms. The greater the interdependency and the more intense the bi- or- multilateral indirect network effects are, the more likely it is that the relevant market will cover more than one side of the platform  (for more on this see previous post). Despite the fact that this challenge has been extensively debated in previous cases dealing with platforms, particularly in the context of Amexthis matter was not explicitly addressed in the case of Google. However that is not to say that no decision on this matter was taken. Quite the contrary, the manner in which the market were defined in this case can be instructive for future practice.

The Android decision covers the definition of four relevant markets that were considered to be affected by Google’s practices, namely (I) the market for licensing of smart mobile OS, (II) the market for Android app stores, (III) the market for the provision of general search services, and (IV) the market for non-OS specific mobile web browsers. In the context of two and multi sided markets it is primarily the first two relevant markets addressed in the decision that are interesting.

I. Google vs. Apple – a matter of perspective

The definition of the market for the licensing of smart mobile OS is undoubtedly the one which was the focus of most debates on the Android decision. This is primarily because the definition of this market was often equated with the question of – are Apple and Google competitors? – which of course they are. Consequently, it is unsurprising that the finding of the Commission that the scope of the relevant market for smart mobile OS does not include Apple raised a few eyebrows. So was the Commission wrong in this matter? No. So how can Apple compete with Google but not be part of the relevant market? The answer is quite simple – asking whether Google and Apple are competitors in abstract has no value for the market definition process if the question is not accompanied by a specific perspective and aim. After all, the market definition process is not an aim in itself and cannot be done in abstract. The case against Google deals primarily with a (multi product) tying abuse. Accordingly, the aim of the market definition process in this case was to help assess whether such tying practices were capable of producing anti-competitive effects. Given that the tying practices were applied with respect to the OEMs it is required that the relevant market and the assessment of market power is performed from that perspective. In other words, the question of substitution is one that needs to be posed with respect to OEMs and not in general terms of Google vs. Apple. This is because in tying cases the relevant market must be defined at the same level of distribution as the tie. Once this approach (which was confirmed in the Microsoft case) is adopted, the conclusion that Apple is not part of the relevant market of Google with regard to app store and smart mobile OS is quite reasonable. After all, from the perspective of OEMs no matter what type of conditions Google introduces in its licensing contracts they could never switch to IOS and/or the App Store. That is not to say that Apple does not pose any competitive pressure on Google as it certainly does, however, that pressure is not with regard to the adoption of Android OS and Play Store by OEMs.


– Ad –

Subscribe to EStAL

The existing enforcement gap on the digital market should be closed with the New Competition Tool, which will complement
ex ante regulations. This online seminar aims to analyze the NCT from a macro to a micro perspective and provide exclusive insights on the NCT in practice. Chaired by the Managing Editors of CoRe journal: Robert Klotz and Ben Van Rompuy, this online seminar is designed to provide you with insights on the latest developments of the NCT. Here is what you may expect:

✓ The New Proposal on the Digital Markets Act (DMA)
✓ Practical Experience from the UK
✓ Panel Discussion: Zoom into the Substance of NCT
✓ Q&A

Register now


II. Number of markets and multi-sided substitutability

The question of how many markets need to be defined for a platform often boils down to the choice between the definition of one or more markets  for the platform depending on the number of customer groups interconnected by it. Although the Android decision does not address this matter as explicitly as previously seen in the credit card cases in the EU and US, a decision on this issue was nonetheless taken implicitly in the assessment of substitutability. In both the market for the licensing of smart mobile OS and the market for Android app stores the number of relevant markets per platform was essentially one. In the case of market for android play store, substitutability was limited to android compatible app stores indicating that a single relevant market was defined for the app store platform including all its customer groups (developers and android users). Similarly, the assessment of substitutability for the Android OS was done, logically, only with respect to other smart mobile OS, meaning that the relevant market covered all the sides of the platform, namely OEMs, developers and consumers. Accordingly, the decision provides yet another example where a single relevant market can be defined for a multi-sided platform despite the skepticism expressed on multiple occasions with regard to the existence and/ or desirability of such an approach (see e.g. the dissenting opinion in the case of Amex).

In addition to this one market approach, the market definition of these two markets also shows how the number of sides of a platform can be a decisive characteristic for substitutability purposes. Due to the fact that Android OS is licensable, it can be seen as a three-sided platform connecting OEMs, developers and consumers. This was similarly the case with some android forks and Windows mobile. By contrast, Apple’s OS and Blackberry’s OS by not being licensable, can be seen as platforms missing the OEM side. This in turn of course limits substitutability among the various smart mobile OS from the perspective of OEMs. If, however, the assessment of substitutability and market power would have been done on the sides of the platforms that concern consumers or developers, the scope of the relevant market may have been different. Unlike OEMs, consumers and developers are likely to be less concerned with the question of licensing when considering switching from one platform to the other. Accordingly, when a single relevant market is defined for a two or multi sided platform the scope of such market will depend greatly on the perspective of the customer group chosen for the assessment and the presence of such customer group on other (potentially substitutable) platforms.

III. Going from SSNIP to SSNRQ  – a welcome but unclear transition

Finally, another interesting issue that can be identified in the context of the market definition in the Android decision is the use of the SSNRQ test as a replacement in of the SSNIP test. Like in the case of most platforms, the majority (if not all) of Google’s products are provided to some of its customer groups (mainly OEMs and consumers) free of charge. Accordingly, when defining the relevant market in such circumstances, the SSNIP test is not a very useful tool since there are no prices to which a theoretical increase can be applied and assessed. An increase of 5-10% of zero will still be equal to zero and theorizing an increase in price from zero to a positive number cannot be considered an adequate mathematical alternative. In light of this problem, it has been suggest to modify the SSNIP test into another tools suitable to deal with zero priced products or services, where the SSNRQ could serve as an alternative. In the case of the SSNRQ the matter of substitution concerns a hypothetical scenario in which the price of zero in maintained, however, the quality of the product or service provided by the dominant undertaking is reduced. Although the test is logically sound, and thus its adoption by the Commission is welcome, its application in practice requires answering some difficult questions which are not always answered in the Android decision.

First, what are the qualities that are selected for such a test and how does the selection process look like? In the Android decision this was done apparently by virtue of a survey made by Google for developers (see para. 286 and footnote 306). One may wonder whether this is the most suitable manner to make the selection in future cases rather than making a specific survey for the purpose of the investigation. Second, it is also important to consider what degree of quality decrease simulates the same effect as a price increase of 5-10%. This information is not included in the decision but would be very important for future practice as it is evidently directly connected to the assessment of substitutability. Third, it is unclear how the SSNRQ (or any test for that matter) should take into account the two or multi sided nature of platforms and the interdependency of demand among their various customer groups. In this matter too it is unclear from the decision how the test incorporated the multi-sided character of the platforms in this case in the process of application.

Conclusion

The Android decision delivers a valuable source of guidance and questions in the case of the market definition for two and multi sided platforms. It solidifies the possibility of defining a single relevant market for a two or multi sided platform that was first seen in Amex but without providing a clear motivation for such (logical) approach. Furthermore, it shows the importance of choosing a specific  perspective and taking into account the multi-sided character of the concerned platform and its (possible) competitors for the purpose of substitutability assessments. Finally, it shows that the Commission is capable of adapting its tools to zero pricing strategies by replacing the SSNIP with the SSNRQ, however, it fall short in delivering the legal and economic justification for such a switch

Tags

Über

Daniel Mandrescu

Blog editor

Ph.D. Fellow, Europa Institute, Leiden University

>> Daniel’s CoRe blog posts >>

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

03. Dez 2020
Features von Daniel Mandrescu

Why you (often) don’t need the essential facility doctrine in the digital economy? – Interpreting Lithuanian Railways and Slovak Telekom

The insights from Lithuanian Railways and Slovak Telekom may have serious implications for the application of the Oscar Bronner case law in the future. These insights may prove, however, to have the most value in the digital economy where it would appear that the essential facility doctrine might often not even be needed – not even in the case of […]
03. Nov 2020
Features von Friso Bostoen
app stores, App Store, Google Play, 30%, commission fee, Epic, Spotify, Netflix, excessive pricing, tying, bundling, exploitation, exclusion, European Commission

Epic v Apple (3): two perspectives on app stores’ 30% commission fee

In a first blog post in this Epic v Apple series, we introduced the high-stakes dispute and the context necessary for understanding it. A second blog post discussed market power in app distribution and access to Apple and Google’s ecosystems under refusal to supply/foreclosure theories of harm. This third post zooms in on the most contentious feature of Apple’s App […]
22. Sep 2020
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
Epic, Fortnite, Apple, battle royale, competition law, antitrust, district court, monopolization, monopoly, essential facilities, refusal to supply, tying, abuse of dominance

Epic v Apple (2): market power and foreclosure in the app distribution market(s)

Epic’s battle against Apple has been extensively covered in media in the past month. This attention is undoubtedly due to Epic’s explicit move against Apple’s terms and conditions as well as Apple’s fierce reaction to cut all ties with Epic. Epic’s legal dispute is, however, not only against Apple but also against Google who has removed Epic from its Play […]
04. Sep 2020
Features von Friso Bostoen
Epic, Fortnite, Apple, battle royale, competition law, antitrust, district court, monopolization, monopoly, essential facilities, refusal to supply, tying, abuse of dominance

Epic v Apple (1): introducing antitrust’s latest Big Tech battle royale

Mid-August 2020, a series of events unfolded in a short period of time. They may prove a watershed moment for the role of antitrust in regulating digital markets. It started when gamers playing Fortnite on their iPhone were suddenly faced with a new choice screen when buying in-app currency: What changed is that Epic, the developer of Fortnite, introduced an […]
09. Jun 2020
Features von Alice Rinaldi
Mobile apps image

Re-imagining the Abuse of Economic Dependence in a Digital World

As proven by the recent consultation on the Digital Services Act, the European Union is actively pursuing new solutions to cope with the challenges posed by digitalization. This post proposes a new approach to conducts taking place in the context of online commercial relationships, such as refusals to access platforms or datasets. Namely, it suggests that the European legislator should […]
23. Apr 2020
Features von Friso Bostoen

Venture capital and antitrust: on exit strategies, killer acquisitions, and innovation harms

Venture capital (VC) is the primary source of financing for early-stage startups bringing their innovation to market. And a disproportionate amount of venture capital goes to startups in the tech sector. However, the last few years have seen a contraction in VC investment, particularly in potential competitors to incumbent digital platforms such as Facebook, Google and Amazon, which some interpret as […]
10. Jan 2020
Features von Friso Bostoen

The antitrust books you should’ve read in 2019 [part 1]

While the past year may not have been spectacular on all fronts, it was a very good one when it came to the publication of antitrust books. New editions of authoritative textbooks were published, including the 7th edition of Jones & Sufrin (the 9th edition of Whish & Bailey was released in 2018). New entrants also dared challenge the incumbents: Lianos, Korah & Siciliani released their own competition […]
27. Nov 2019
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
Android with cookies

Lessons and questions from Google Android- Part 2 – Tying in two-sided markets, anti-competitive effects and extra-territorial remedies

The very lengthy and complex Google Android decision provides us with lots of material for discussion. In the first part of this discussion the matter of the definition of the relevant market was addressed. Although it may appear that this is the only key issue in the case, the decision covers several other issues, which deserve equal (if not more) attention. […]
07. Okt 2019
CoRe News von Lexxion Publisher

Are You Joining Us? 24 Oct 2019, Conference in Brussels: Dynamic Competition in Dynamic Markets

CoRe is partnering up with our friends from across the Atlantic – Competition Policy International (CPI) – for the 1-day conference Dynamic Competition in Dynamic Markets: A Path Forward. You can attend for free but you have to register first. The event is on 24 October 2019, at The Hotel in Brussels. Last seats available so be quick – we’re closing registration soon […]
14. Jun 2019
Features von Friso Bostoen

U.S. antitrust agencies divide jurisdiction over Big Tech and single out Google for investigation

Last year, I wrote about how the United States considers boarding the tech regulation train that has been racing through Europe. It seems that they have now taken another decisive step in that direction: the U.S. antitrust agencies have agreed that the Department of Justice (DOJ) will oversee investigations of Google and Apple, while the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) is responsible for antitrust […]

Nutzen Sie unseren Newsletter, um sich regelmäßig über Konferenzen, Workshops, Trainings und die  neuesten Ausgaben unserer Fachzeitschriften u.a. aus den Bereichen des europäischen Wettbewerbs- und Vergaberechte, Datenschutzrechte, Abfallrecht, Umwelt- und Planungsrecht sowie Chemikalien- und Pharmarecht zu informieren.

Verpassen Sie keine Events und Publikationen. Neuigkeiten abonnieren