Identification of the Reference Tax System: The Case of a Tax on Advertising Turnover

Identification of the Reference Tax System: The Case of a Tax on Advertising Turnover - m 20

Turnover taxes should be levied at a single rate.

Introduction

This is the fourth case involving turnover taxes that have been declared to be incompatible with the internal market [see Commission decision 2017/329].[1] A brief summary was published here on 13 December 2016 [http://stateaidhub.eu/blogs/stateaiduncovered/post/7697].

The reasoning of the Commission follows closely that of the other cases. However, what makes this case particularly interesting is the explanation why the whole “reference” system is selective and why the selectivity cannot be justified.

In 2014 Hungary imposed a tax on advertising activities. The tax was levied on gross turnover [i.e. before deduction of costs] derived from the publication of advertisements in public media. The taxable persons were publishers of advertisements in newspapers, magazines, internet sites, etc.

The rates of the tax varied between 0% and 1% for companies with small or medium-sized advertising turnover and 50% for companies with high advertising turnover. More precisely, the rates were defined as follows:

turnover below HUF 0.5 billion: 0%
turnover between HUF 0.5 billion and 5 billion: 1%
turnover between HUF 5 billion and 10 billion: 10%
turnover between HUF 10 billion and 15 billion: 20%
turnover between HUF 15 billion and 20 billion: 30%
turnover above HUF 20 billion: 50%

Hungary defended the progressive nature of the advertising tax on the grounds that it was linked to the ability of each company to pay for public policies. [In the same measure there was a provision for deduction from the corporate tax base of losses carried forward from previous years. This provision is not examined here.]

Interestingly, according to the Commission decision, the total revenue from the advertising tax was HUF 2,640,100,000 [about EUR 8,500,000]. Approximately 80% of that revenue was paid by just one group of companies.

The Commission considered that “(26) […] the progressive tax rates differentiate between undertakings with high advertisement revenues (and thus larger undertakings) and undertakings with low advertisement revenues (and thus smaller undertakings), and grant a selective advantage to the latter based on their size.”

Existence of State aid

There was no doubt that the tax, if found to be selective, transferred state resources in favour of smaller advertisers and had the potential to affect trade and distort competition. The crucial question was whether it was a selective measure.

The progressive character of the tax meant that “(44) […] undertakings with low turnover (smaller undertakings) are taxed at a substantially lower average rate than undertakings with high turnover (larger undertakings). Being taxed at this substantially lower average tax rate mitigates the charges that undertakings with low turnover have to bear as compared to undertakings with high turnover and therefore constitutes an advantage to the benefit of smaller undertakings over larger undertakings for the purposes of Article 107(1) of the Treaty.”

With respect to the question whether the tax was selective, the Commission first explained that “(46) […] the Court of Justice has established that the selectivity of [a tax] should in principle be assessed by means of a three-step analysis. First, the common or normal tax regime applicable in the Member State is identified: ‘the reference system’. Second, it should be determined whether a given measure constitutes a derogation from that system insofar as it differentiates between economic operators who, in light of the objectives intrinsic to the system, are in a comparable factual and legal situation. If the measure in question does not constitute a derogation from the reference system, it is not selective. If it does (and therefore is prima facie selective), it must be established, in the third step of the analysis, whether the derogatory measure is justified by the nature or the general scheme of the reference tax system. If a prima facie selective measure is justified by the nature or the general scheme of the system, it will not be considered selective and it will thus fall outside the scope of Article 107(1) of the Treaty.”


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner

The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

Step 1: What is the system of reference?

“(48) In the present case, the reference system is the application of a special advertisement tax on turnover derived from the provision of advertising services […] The Commission does not consider that the progressive rate structure of the advertisement tax can form a part of that reference system.”

The Commission does not really explain at this point why it excludes from the analysis the progressive rate structure, nor why including it would affect its conclusions. But as it becomes more obvious from its reasoning later on, it is the progressive structure that makes the system selective. Therefore, the reference system is just the taxation of advertising revenue.

At any rate, the Commission goes on to explain that “(49) as the Court of Justice has specified, it is not always sufficient to confine the selectivity analysis to whether a measure derogates from the reference system as defined by the Member State. It is also necessary to evaluate whether the boundaries of that system have been designed by the Member State in a consistent manner or, conversely, in a clearly arbitrary or biased way, so as to favour certain undertakings over others. Otherwise, instead of laying down general rules applying to all undertakings from which a derogation is made for certain undertakings, the Member State could achieve the same result, side stepping the State aid rules, by adjusting and combining its rules in such a way that their very application results in a different burden for different undertakings.”

This approach makes sense. For example, the exception of SMEs from a corporate tax is clearly a selective measure falling within the scope of Article 107(1) TFEU. But the same result can be achieved by a tax that is levied only on large enterprises. If the objective of such a measure is to tax corporate profit then SMEs are in the same situation as large enterprises and the non-application of the tax to SMEs favours SMEs over other companies.

In other words, the identification of the reference system contains an inherent but not visible comparison between the stated objective of the tax in question and the scope of application of that tax. The tax should not apply to any person or activity that is truly different. Conversely, it should apply to all similar persons or activities.

Indeed, “(50) the progressive tax structure […] appears deliberately designed by Hungary to favour certain undertakings over others.” But “(52) because each company is taxed at a different rate, it is not possible for the Commission to identify one single reference rate in the advertisement tax. Hungary did not present any specific rate as the reference rate or ‘normal’ rate and did not explain either why a higher rate would be justified for undertakings with a high level of turnover, nor why lower rates should apply to undertakings with lower levels of advertisement turnover.”

The Commission went on to reject the Hungarian argument that the “(53) […] objective of the advertisement tax is to promote the principle of public burden sharing. In light of that objective, the Commission considers all operators subject to the advertisement tax to be in a comparable legal and factual situation. As a consequence, unless it is duly justified, all operators should be treated equally and pay the same proportion of their turnover, regardless of their level of turnover. The Commission observes that the consequence of the application of a single tax rate to all operators is already that those with higher turnovers contribute more to the State budget than those with low turnovers. Hungary has advanced no convincing argument justifying the discrimination between those types of undertakings by progressively imposing a proportionately higher tax burden on those with a higher advertisement turnover. Hungary has therefore deliberately designed the advertisement tax in such a manner so as to arbitrarily favour certain undertakings, namely those with a lower level of turnover (and thus smaller undertakings), and disadvantage others, namely larger undertakings.”

“(54) The reference system is therefore selective by design in a way that is not justified in light of the objective of the advertisement tax, which is to promote the principle of public burden sharing and collect funds for the State budget.”

“(56) In the Commission’s view, the reference system for the taxation of advertisement turnover should be a tax on advertisement turnover which would comply with State aid rules i.e. where:

– advertisement turnovers are subject to the same (single) tax rate,
– no other element is maintained or introduced that would provide a selective advantage to certain undertakings.”

Step 2: Does the measure derogate from the reference system?

According to the Commission, “(58) the progressivity of the advertisement tax rate structure creates a differentiation amongst undertakings […] based on the scale of their advertisement activity.” “(59) […] As a result, undertakings with low turnover are subject to both substantially lower marginal tax rates and substantially lower average tax rates as compared to undertakings with high levels of turnover, and therefore to substantially lower taxation for the same activities.” “(61) Hence, the Commission considers that the progressive rate structure introduced by the Act derogates from the reference system consisting of the imposition of an advertisement tax on all operators involved in the publication of advertisements in Hungary in favour of undertakings with lower turnover.”

In other words, we have the unusual situation here where the reference system is the objective of the tax [to tax advertising turnover] and the selective aspect of the measure is its progressive rates.

Step 3: Is the selectivity justified by the nature and general scheme of the tax system?

Selectivity is justified when it is the result of “(66) […] inherent mechanisms necessary for the functioning and effectiveness of the system. It is for the Member State to provide such justification.

As mentioned above, the Commission had already rejected the argument of Hungary that the turnover and the size of undertakings reflected their ability to pay and therefore to contribute to the cost of public policies. “(67) The Commission considers that […] neither that the turnover of a group of companies is a good proxy for its ability to pay nor that the pattern of progressivity of the tax is justified by the nature and general scheme of the tax system.” “(68) It is a natural consequence of (single-rate) turnover taxes that the bigger the turnover of a company is, the more tax it pays. As opposed to taxes based on profit, a turnover-based tax is however not intended to take into account — and indeed does not take into account — any of the costs incurred in the generation of that turnover. Therefore, […], the level of turnover generated cannot automatically be considered as reflecting the ability to pay of the undertaking.”

The Commission explained that the “(69) […] progressive rates for taxes on turnover could only be justified exceptionally, that is if the specific objective pursued by a tax indeed requires progressive rates. Progressive turnover taxes could, for example, be justified if the externalities created by an activity that the tax is supposed to tackle also increase progressively – i.e. more than proportionately – with its turnover. However, Hungary did not provide any justification of the progressivity of the tax by the externalities possibly created by advertisement.”

The Commission concluded that the measure was selective and, because it satisfied all of the criteria of Article 107(1), it constitute State aid.

Since the aid was operating aid it was found to be incompatible with the internal market. In principle operating aid for regional development purposes is allowed under certain conditions in Article 107(3)(a) areas. Hungary does have such areas. But the Hungarian authorities provided no evidence that the aid was granted in compliance with the regional rules on operating aid. Consequently, the Commission ordered the recovery of the aid.

How much aid had to be recovered?

Legally, it is the obligation of the Member State that granted the incompatible aid to propose to the Commission how it intends to recover the aid and how much to recover. But it is customary for the Commission to provide guidance to Member States in recovery decisions how to calculate the amount of aid that is to be recovered.

Since in this case there was no standard rate from which a reduction had been granted, the Commission decided that “(91) […] recovery of the aid means that Hungary needs to treat all undertakings equally as if they had been subject to a single fixed rate. By default, the Commission considers that the single fixed rate to be 5.3% as determined by Hungary in the amended version of the tax unless Hungary decides, within two months from the date of adoption of the present decision, to set a different level for the single tax rate that will apply retroactively to all undertakings over the whole period of application of the advertisement tax (original and amended versions) or to abolish the advertisement tax retroactively as of the date of its entry into force.”

“(93) As stated in recital 56, the reference system for the taxation of advertisement turnover would be a tax where:

– all advertisement turnovers are subject to the tax (no optionality), without the deduction of any loss carried- forward,
– turnovers are subject to the same (single) tax rate; by default, this single rate is set at 5.3%,
– no other element is maintained or introduced that would provide a selective advantage to certain undertakings.”

“(94) As regards recovery, this means that […] the amount of aid received by the companies with advertisement turnover should be calculated as the difference between:

– on the one hand, the amount of tax (1) that the undertaking should have paid under the application of the reference system in line with State aid rules (with a single tax rate of, by default, 5.3% to the entire advertisement turnover without the deduction of any loss carried-forward),
– on the other hand, the amount of tax (2) that the undertaking was liable to pay or had already paid.”

“(95) To the extent that the difference between amount of tax (1) and amount of tax (2) is positive, the amount of aid should be recovered including recovery interest as of the date the tax was due.”

Hungary did not have to recover aid whose amount fell below the de minimis threshold of EUR 200,000 and all other conditions of the de minimis regulation were complied with.

Lastly, it is worth observing that the decision is silent on what happens when the difference between (1) and (2) is negative. That is when the advertising revenue was subject to a rate that exceeded 5.3%. Would Hungary return the excess tax back to the undertaking that had paid 80% of the total revenue raised by the tax?

—————————————————

[1] The decision is published in the OJ L49, 25 February 2017. It can be accessed at:

http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=uriserv:OJ.L_.2017.049.01.0036.01.ENG&toc=OJ:L:2017:049:TOC.

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Kommentar

  1. von Dr Eugene Stuart

    This case is one too far by the Commission and directly interferes in national sovereignty to set up progression in tax measures. The argumentation is very vague in places and it may well be a politically driven decision

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

11. Dez 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Member States Have Discretion to Determine their Own Tax System and Interpret its Provisions - Untitled design 29

Member States Have Discretion to Determine their Own Tax System and Interpret its Provisions

Introduction In the landmark cases on turnover taxes implemented by Hungary and Poland, the Court of Justice censured the European Commission for defining its own hypothetical reference tax system that was different from the relevant tax provisions in those two countries. The Court again faulted the Commission in its more recent judgments on advance tax rulings. Given the discretion of […]
22. Nov 2022
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The “Arm’s Length Principle” and the Taxation of Transactions between Related Companies - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 8

The “Arm’s Length Principle” and the Taxation of Transactions between Related Companies

The arm’s length principle is not an autonomous principle that can be applied to any advance tax ruling. It must be provided in the national tax system. Furthermore, the arm’s length principle must be applied, if it exists in the national tax system, in the form that is defined by that tax system. Introduction In a series of decisions beginning […]
11. Okt 2022
von Phedon Nicolaides
Selectivity of Regional Schemes - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 4

Selectivity of Regional Schemes

Introduction Article 107(3)(a) areas and the outermost regions of the EU [defined in Article 349 TFEU] are more favourably treated under State aid rules. But they still have to comply with the terms of Commission authorising decisions. In case regional State aid is found to be incompatible with the internal market, their regional handicaps cannot justify any leniency in the […]
11. Mai 2021
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides

State Aid Measures May not be Funded through Discriminatory Taxes

A tax that is levied on both imported and domestic products but its revenue finances only domestic products infringes fundamental provisions of the EU Treaty. Introduction Member States finance the generation of electricity from renewable energy sources [RES] with revenue they raise through levies or charges on consumers of electricity. On 14 April 2021, the General Court in judgment in […]
14. Jul 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
report

2019 Competition Report

The Annual Competition Report is a useful document, but it should provide more information on the results of the ex post evaluations and ex post monitoring. Update on Temporary Framework: Number of approved and published COVID-19 measures, as of 10 July 2020: 202* Legal basis: Article 107(2)(b): 20; Article 107(3)(b): 171; Article 107(3)(c): 17 Six Member States have implemented 11 […]
17. Mrz 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Has an Economic Myth Become a Legal Fact? The Case of Turnover Taxes - Turnover

Has an Economic Myth Become a Legal Fact? The Case of Turnover Taxes

Progressive turnover taxes are not contrary to the freedom of establishment or the right of equal treatment. Introduction Recent cases involving “turnover” taxes have sparked a debate in the literature and on the conference circuit not only because they raise novel issues but also because of their implications for other taxes which are being mooted by European governments. As Advocate-General […]
30. Jul 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The Problem with Turnover Taxes -

The Problem with Turnover Taxes

Economies of scale do not necessarily correlate with ability to pay. Introduction On Thursday, 11 July 2019, France became the first European country to adopt a tax on digital sales. At about the same time, President Donald Trump warned that the US would retaliate with punitive tariffs. The US believes that the tax is aimed at its internet giants such […]