Financial Transactions between the State and Banks with No State aid

Financial Transactions between the State and Banks with No State aid - StateAidHub blogpost10 state guarantees scaled

Capital injections, state guarantees and loans granted to banks can be free of State aid if they are priced at market rates which reflect the risk borne by the state.

Introduction

If banks can obtain capital, loans and guarantees from the state at market rates why don’t they go directly to the market? No one has yet given a satisfactory answer to this question. During the past decade at least three theories have been advanced by speakers at various conferences to explain this conundrum.

The first is that the Commission has simply accommodated the interventionist instincts of Member States to prevent the collapse of the European economy. I think the Commission has indeed acted effectively and with flexibility but on the whole it has enforced State aid rules rigorously. The three cases which are reviewed in this article attest to that.

The second theory is that governments do not really intend to stick to the commitments they make and that they will use every trick in the book to confer covert advantages to banks after the Commission gives its approval. Perhaps there is an element of truth in this theory but there is no firm evidence to support that this is a wide practice.

The third theory is more serious and if true it should lead to rethink of the rules on State aid to banks. It goes as follows. In periods of market turbulence and increased uncertainty, the normal market indicators such as credit ratings lose their significance. Market operators become excessively risk averse. Indeed we have seen wild swings in market sentiment from overly optimistic to overly pessimistic. The only way to induce investors to overcome their heightened risk aversion is for the government to invest a big enough chunk of money that can absorb a large proportion of possible losses. So, according to this theory, even if the state co-invests on equal terms with private investors, in fact, without a commitment by the state no private investment can be forthcoming.

If this theory is true the unavoidable consequence must be that state investments must carry a premium. In other words, the state should earn a higher return than the prevailing market rate for the same presumed risk and same amount. This is easy to say but immensely more difficult to quantify and apply in practice. But perhaps the Commission should consider it and put to rest the suspicion that richer Member States have an advantage over poorer Member States with fewer disposable resources.

I. Capital injection in a bank

In decision SA.49094, the Commission assessed several measures for the strengthening of the capital base and restructuring of Norddeutsche Landesbank or NordLB.[1] The measures were assessed individually and each was found to be market conform.

NordLB is majority state owned and it is the fourth largest Landesbank bank in Germany. In 2011 and 2012, NordLB received State aid amounting EUR 0.5 billion and EUR 0.9 billion, respectively. Nonetheless, the bank continued to suffer losses, mostly from non-performing loans to shipping companies.

The measures that are the subject of decision SA.49094 were intended to streamline the bank and return it to viability.

Sale of assets

NordLB proposed to sell two assets to the Land of Lower Saxony. The German authorities valued the two assets using a discounted cash-flow method [DCF]. The Commission’s external experts used the same method but with more conservative parameters.

The external experts estimated a sales price for the assets between EUR [100-150] million and EUR [150-200] million.

The Commission considered that the proposed sales price of EUR 150 million was “well within this range” and that NordLB would not derive any advantage.

Asset guarantees

The Commission noted that all three asset guarantee contracts confer to a Trustee the task of ensuring that the Land of Lower Saxony would pursue its own economic interest.

Because the non-performing loans in those assets have no comparable market rate, the Commission’s external experts estimated their value according to the present value of the expected cash flows.

Direct capital injection

NordLB’s business plan aimed for significant cost reductions, some asset decrease and some revenue increase.

The Commission considered all three aims to be realistic. The Commission also examined the funding cost of the various actions foreseen in the business plan and concluded that the costs were credible as they were equivalent to the credit spreads expected for senior preferred bond and that they were comparable to observable CDS spreads for NordLB.

The relevant benchmark for the cost of equity [CoE] was ranging between [8% and 10%] and calculated on the basis of the CAPM. The derived IRR was [9% – 14%].

Although, those values were far above the risk-free rate of 0% and the country risk premium of 0% for Germany, the Commission recalculated the IRR and arrived at a value of 8.9%, which was close to the middle of the range of 8% to 10%.

Coverage of extra health-care cost

The relevant public authorities required NordLB to increase its provisions for the health care of its staff. The possible extra costs were covered by a state guarantee.

An actuary estimated the possible extra costs as normal business practice based on long-term trends. The one-off guarantee fee was found to be more than the expected costs.

II. State guarantees for the securitisation of non-performing loans

Some EU banks still have a large number of non-performing loans [NPLs]. This makes them vulnerable to any downturn in the market and reduces their leeway to grant new loans. One way to reduce the proportion of these NPLs in their assets is to raise new capital. Another way to deal with them is simply to get rid of them. The problem is that the market is reluctant to buy portfolios of loans of shaky quality. For this reason, some governments have granted State aid to banks to help them bridge the gap between the book value and the price at which the loans are sold. Some other governments have guaranteed the value of bonds issued for the purpose of raising fresh capital. Yet some other governments have guaranteed the value of packages of NPLs sold to investors.

In decision SA.53519, the European Commission assessed such a state guarantee for the securitisation of NPLs disposed by Greek banks and concluded that it was free of State aid because the guarantee premium corresponded to the market fee that would be charged by a private market operator.[2]

The measure was voluntary and open to any bank. The guarantee covered only the senior tranche of the “securitisation structures”. The junior tranche would bear fully any gains or losses. A participating bank would have to appoint an independent “servicer” to work out the underlying NPLs in the securitisation structures. Part of the fee to be paid to the servicer would be linked to achievement of performance targets.

 


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid? 

EStAL banner

The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

Pricing of the state guarantee

The premium charged for the guarantee was equal to the market price of the risk borne by the state. The risk was calculated by taking as a base the price of the credit default swaps for Greece and then adjusting it upwards to reflect the specific quality of each securitisation structure.

Notice on Guarantees

The Commission assessed the Greek measure according to the principles laid down in its 2008 Notice on Guarantees. First, the Commission noted that a guarantee scheme is free of State aid when:

“(a) The scheme is closed to borrowers in financial difficulties;

(b) The guarantee amount can be measured when it is granted;

(c) The guarantee cannot cover more than 80% of the outstanding financial obligation;

(d) The remuneration is based on a realistic assessment of the risk and the premiums paid so that the scheme can be considered self-financing;

(e) The level of premiums has to be reviewed at least every 12 months in view of the self-financing nature of the scheme;

(f) The premiums charged have to cover the normal risks associated with granting the guarantee, the administrative costs and a yearly remuneration on the necessary capital.” [paragraph 46 of the decision]

Then the Commission pointed out that it “(47) cannot exclude that the Scheme is open to borrowers in financial difficulty or might be used in specific circumstances to provide guarantees covering more than 80% of the outstanding financial obligation. The Commission therefore considers it likely that these conditions will not be fulfilled in all instances of the Scheme’s usage.”

Since it could not rely on the principles in the Guarantee Notice, it went on to consider whether the fee charged for the guarantee in this case corresponded to the premium that a market operator would have charged.

Excessive risk?

In paragraphs 52-56, the Commission assessed the risk assumed by the Greek state. It found that:

First, the NPLs’ management was transferred to an independent servicer whose fee would partly be linked to performance. This would increase the likely recovery and reduce the risk of miscalculation of the actual value of the NPLs.

Second, the senior tranche would have a fully preferred status. No money would be paid to the junior tranche before the senior tranche would be repaid in full.

Third, the exposure of the Greek government was confined to the senior tranche of the securitisation structure.

Fourth, the credit rating of the senior tranche and the size of the loss-absorbing tranches would be established by an independent expert.

Fifth, the scheme was design in such a way so that the guarantee would be effective only when at least 50% of the junior tranches would be sold to private investors. That meant that the state guarantee on the senior tranche would “in effect guarantee less than the transfer value of the underlying assets.”

Market price?

The Commission also found, in paragraphs 59-78, that the remuneration of the state for its guarantee reflected all the elements that a private market operator would take into account and corresponded to the amount of risk borne by the state. In fact the fee was estimated conservatively because it included an extra margin.

Again the Commission assessed positively the fact that the junior tranche would be paid after the senior tranche and that the guarantee would become operational only after the majority of the junior tranche was sold.

III. Remuneration for funds deposited at a state treasury

The Italian postal service, Poste Italiane [PI] is authorised to operate savings accounts. Italian law requires PI to deposit the accumulated funds from the millions of accounts it manages into a single account at the Italian Treasury. The Commission investigated this arrangement and concluded in decision 2009/179 of July 2008 that it involved incompatible State aid because the rate of interest obtained by PI was higher than what a prudent private borrower would have paid. It was also higher than the rate of interest PI paid to its own  savers.

The Commission reached that conclusion after it considered the amount, stability and average duration of deposited funds and the financial risk borne by the state.

However, in September 2013, the General Court found, in an appeal lodged by PI, that the Commission erred in law and annulled the decision of the Commission [case T-525/08, Poste Italiane v Commission].

As a result, the Commission re-opened the case and concluded afresh in decision 2019/1968 that the remuneration received by PI was free of State aid.[3]

The Commission explained as follows the reasoning of the General Court:

“(31) The existence of a positive difference between the [Treasury’s] rate and the rate granted to the prudent private borrower was not sufficient to demonstrate an advantage for PI. […] (33) The General Court noted that even if the rate granted to the prudent private borrower was not at the level of the market rate, PI would benefit from an advantage only if the [Treasury’s] rate was higher than the return PI could have reasonably achieved in the absence of the Obligation. (34) The General Court determined that the Commission could not conclude that the measure benefitted PI without actively demonstrating that, in the absence of the Obligation, PI could not have gotten a higher return by investing the deposits from the postal current accounts as compared to the Treasury’s rate.”

It is difficult to understand the reasoning of the Court. In essence the Court criticised the Commission for not proving that in the counterfactual situation it would have been impossible for PI to earn more. But was a hypothetical counterfactual relevant given the fact that PI was obliged by law to deposit savers’ funds at the Italian Treasury? And, more importantly, given that PI was a “captive” customer of the Treasury why would the Treasury, acting as a rational market operator, pay anything more than the cost borne by PI for managing those funds?

In order to assist it in its re-assessment, the Commission requested an analysis of yields of various alternative investment strategies by an independent expert. Although the Commission did not completely agree with the findings of the independent expert, it decided that “(121) the expected rate under the [agreement between the Treasury and PI] is lower than the expected return of alternative investment strategies, in a stationary rate scenario, at similar risk levels, in the absence of the Obligation. As a result, the rate under the [agreement] did not entail an immediate advantage for PI.”

As pointed out above, it is unclear why alternative investment strategies are relevant at all, given that PI was legally obliged to deposit funds at the Treasury.

—————————————————————————-

[1] The full text of the Commission decision can be accessed at:

https://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases1/20203/283125_2123117_150_5.pdf.

[2] The full text of the Commission decision can be accessed at:

https://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases1/201945/282211_2106701_128_2.pdf.

[3] The full text of the Commission decision can be accessed at:

https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=uriserv:OJ.L_.2019.307.01.0028.01.ENG&toc=OJ:L:2019:307:TOC.

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

30. Apr 2024
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Case of a Narrow Tax that Is Not Selective - State Aid Uncovered photos 11

A Case of a Narrow Tax that Is Not Selective

Introduction On 17 April 2024, the General Court ruled, in case T-112/22, Ideella föreningen Svenska Bankföreningen med firma Svenska Bankföreningen, Näringsverksamhet & Länsförsäkringar Bank v Commission, that a Swedish tax on only nine banks was not selective by not taxing the many smaller banks.1 The applicants, a Swedish banking association and a Swedish bank, respectively, sought the annulment of Commission […]
26. Mrz 2024
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Applying the Funding Gap Method to an Important Project of Common European Interest – Part II - State Aid Uncovered photos 7

Applying the Funding Gap Method to an Important Project of Common European Interest – Part II

Introduction On 28 February 2024, the General Court delivered an important judgment in case T-390/20, Scandlines v Commission.(1) The judgment is important because it interpreted the Commission guidelines on Important Projects of Common European Interest [IPCEI], the funding gap methodology for determining the necessary amount of aid and the 2008 Commission Notice on state guarantees. Scandlines sought annulment of Commission […]
19. Mrz 2024
von Phedon Nicolaides
Applying the Funding Gap Method to an Important Project of Common European Interest – Part I - State Aid Uncovered photos 1

Applying the Funding Gap Method to an Important Project of Common European Interest – Part I

Introduction On 28 February 2024, the General Court delivered an important judgment in case T-390/20, Scandlines v Commission.(1) The judgment is important because it interpreted the Commission guidelines on Important Projects of Common European Interest [IPCEI], the funding gap methodology for determining the necessary amount of aid and the 2008 Commission Notice on state guarantees. Scandlines sought annulment of Commission […]
14. Feb 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The European Commission in not Responsible for the Bail-in of Investors in Banks - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 26

The European Commission in not Responsible for the Bail-in of Investors in Banks

Introduction Investors in banks that failed or were restructured as a result of the financial crisis that broke out in 2008 have tried many times and have used many arguments to support their claims for compensation. None of them has so far succeeded before EU courts to prove that the Commission, or the ECB or the Council or the Eurogroup […]
20. Sep 2022
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
An Innovative Scheme to Support Individual Borrowers - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 31

An Innovative Scheme to Support Individual Borrowers

Individuals and households are not undertakings. However, any public funding of individuals or households may constitute indirect aid to undertakings. Such aid may be exempted on the basis of Article 107(2)(a) TFEU. Introduction Article 107(1) TFEU applies to indirect State aid as well as to direct aid. Since all State aid has both primary effects [i.e. the benefits that go […]
23. Mrz 2021
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Exclusive Rights and State Aid - StateAidHub blogpost12 Poste Italiane

Exclusive Rights and State Aid

Exclusive rights may constitute State aid if they mandate payments with resources over which the state can exercise control. Compensation for the cost of public service obligations may be granted only if the obligations are clear and define a service that is different from market services. Introduction Article 106(1) TFEU requires Member States not to distort competition when they grant […]
09. Mrz 2021
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Can the Decision of a Private Entity be Imputed to the State? - StateAidHub blogpost7 Bank Italy

Can the Decision of a Private Entity be Imputed to the State?

A measure is imputable to the state whenever the state is involved in its adoption or shapes the decision that leads to its adoption. Introduction One of the trickiest aspects of determining whether a financial transaction involves State aid is its attribution or imputation to a decision of the state, especially when the entity providing the funding is private. Private […]
13. Okt 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Market Economy Operator Principle: The Case of FIH - danish currency 1139103 1920

Market Economy Operator Principle: The Case of FIH

Negotiated transactions are not necessarily market conform. Update on Temporary Framework: Number of approved and published covid-19 measures, as of 9 October 2020: 295* Legal basis: Article 107(2)(b): 32; Article 107(3)(b): 248; Article 107(3)(c): 23 – Average number of measures per Member State: 10.5 – Median number of measures per Member State: 12 – Mode number of measures per Member […]
08. Sep 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
State Control without State Imputability - Postnord

State Control without State Imputability

A snapshot of Covid-19 State aid Number of Covid-19 approved measures1, 2 [EU27 + UK, 4 September 2020] 19-15 13-11 9-7 6-4 BE CZ DK IT PL DE FR HU LV NL BG EL FI IE LT LU MT RO SE SK UK AT CY EE ES HR PT SI Source: DG Competition, author’s own calculations 1: Data exclude amendments […]
14. Jul 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
report

2019 Competition Report

The Annual Competition Report is a useful document, but it should provide more information on the results of the ex post evaluations and ex post monitoring. Update on Temporary Framework: Number of approved and published COVID-19 measures, as of 10 July 2020: 202* Legal basis: Article 107(2)(b): 20; Article 107(3)(b): 171; Article 107(3)(c): 17 Six Member States have implemented 11 […]