Services of General Economic Interest and Horse Racing

horse racing

Introduction

Public authorities often argue that the activities they support are important and that they should be considered as services of general economic interest. However, in many cases they are not. In this article I review the Commission Decision 2014/19 concerning a parafiscal levy that was intended to fund supposedly public service obligations assigned to French horse racing companies.[1] This Decision is notable because it deals with alleged SGEI, because it illustrates how parafiscal charges are assessed by the Commission and, unfortunately, because the reasoning on the compatibility of the State aid with the internal market is particularly sloppy.

Background

France notified to the Commission a proposal for a parafiscal levy on online horse-race betting in order to fund a public service mission entrusted to horse racing companies. France opened up the online gambling sector to competition in May 2010. Its aim was to put a stop to the growing illegal gambling activities on the internet. Three types of game were opened up to competition: online horse-race betting, sports betting and poker games. Online gambling and betting operators must be in possession of an authorisation, issued for a term of five years and under certain conditions.

Prior to the opening-up to competition, the monopoly of horse-race betting conducted outside race courses was held by the PMU (Pari Mutuel Urbain).[2] The PMU is the leading betting operator in Europe and the second largest in the world. Its entire net revenue is paid to horse racing companies and it is used to fund 80% of the horse racing and equine industry (breeding, training centres, horse riding schools, etc.), which employs some 74,000 people and is present in every region in France with a total of 250 race courses. Given the importance of the PMU in the financing of the horse racing and equine industry, the French authorities were concerned that the sustainability of the industry would be under threat if the opening-up to competition of the online gambling sector resulted in a significant drop in the PMU’s revenues.

Consequently, France decided to introduce a parafiscal levy on online horse-race betting in favour of the horse racing and equine industry, in order to prevent the economic destabilisation of the sector as a result of the opening-up to competition and its potentially harmful consequences. The parafiscal levy on online horse-race betting would finance a service of general economic interest [SGEI] entrusted to the horse racing companies. The levy would be calculated as follows:

Levy = (net cost of public service obligations)/(horse-race betting stakes)

In 2010, the total horse-race stakes [both online and in-shop] were EUR 9,286 million.

France argued in the notification that the horse racing companies provided a public service made up of the following elements: improving the equine species; promoting horse breeding; personnel training in the horse racing and horse breeding sector; rural development.

In practice, horse racing companies were regulated and operated under the following obligations: the distribution of premiums and allowances to breeders, owners and jockeys; the organisation of races, including the maintenance and building of race courses; drug testing; training courses; and social welfare initiatives in horse racing. The total net cost of these obligations came to approximately EUR 747 million in 2010.


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

Because the Commission had doubts whether the actual obligations of the horse racing companies and their proposed future obligations described in the notification were in fact SGEI, it opened the formal investigation procedure. In particular, the Commission was of the opinion that i) betting and horse racing did not satisfy a general need and that ii) compensation for public service obligations normally goes to companies that provide direct services to the public. The compensation is normally not reserved for the costs borne by particular industry or sector, which are not directly related to services provided to the public. For example, in this case the notification referred to the costs of horse breeding and improvement of the equine species. These are not related to costs of services provided directly to the public. The Commission also had doubts concerning the compatibility of the levy with internal market principles such as the freedom to provide services.

Consequently, in April 2013 France submitted to the Commission an amendment to their initial notification. In the amended notification, the measure for the financing of horse racing was no longer a compensation for a public service entrusted to the horse racing companies. Instead, the calculation of the level of the tax to be levied on all online horse-race betting operators took into account only compensation for the costs of organising races that also benefitted all online horse-race betting operators (the so-called “common interest costs”). The new system reduced the level of the costs to be financed by the revenues generated by the parafiscal levy because they were limited only to the costs of horse races for which betting occurred online [for certain local horse races there was online betting interest]. The new levy was calculated as follows:

Levy = (net common interest costs)/(horse-race betting stakes) =

= (costs – revenue)/(horse-race betting stakes).

Whilst in the first notification [with the public service obligation] the levy was 8%, in the second notification [with common interest costs] the levy was 5.6%.

Existence of State aid

There was no doubt that the levy constituted State aid. The levy on online bets was imposed by a decision of the State. The collected revenue was distributed to horse racing companies. Horse betting is an international activity where both punters and betting companies from different Member States are involved. Therefore, all of the criteria of Article 107(1) were satisfied.

Assessment of compatibility

There were two challenges in the assessment of the compatibility of the levy. First, the State aid measure was financed by a parafiscal charge. Second, in the absence of any guidelines, the measure had to be assessed directly on the basis of Article 107(3)(c) and be subject to the balancing test.

i) Compatibility of the parafiscal levy

With respect to the fact that the funding of the measure came from a parafiscal charge, the Commission explained in paragraph 131 of its Decision that it had declared compatible “several cases of aid to finance, via a levy on businesses in a given sector, joint activities carried on for the benefit of the sector as a whole, where the purpose of those measures was to promote technical progress, improve the quality, competitiveness and productivity of the businesses and adapt them to the needs of the market.” It also provided examples from its decisional practice: N 472/2000, parafiscal charge imposed with a view to financing joint initiatives by the Inter-trade Committee for the Development of the Leather Goods and Footwear Industries. N 163/2002: parafiscal charge imposed for the purpose of financing joint initiatives by the national Cognac trade association. N 496/2000: parafiscal charge on clockmaking, jewellery and goldsmith’s trade goods imposed for the purpose of financing joint initiatives by the Inter-trade Committee for the development of the clockmaking, jewellery, and goldsmith’s trades.

But the Commission’s main worry was that the levy could impede free trade in services under Article 56 TFEU and discriminate against foreign products under Article 110 TFEU. The Commission identified three possible levels of discrimination and obstruction of the principle of freedom to provide services.

First, there could be discrimination in the allocation of certain premiums. European operators who are not established in France would thus be taxed in order to finance premiums that would benefit only the breeders and owners of horses born and bred in France. In order to remove this kind of discrimination, France excluded from the calculation of the common costs to be financed by the levy all those premiums which are reserved for horses born and bred in France.

Second, there could be discrimination between horse-race betting operators if the levy financed costs that were of greater benefit to the horse racing companies and the PMU than to other betting operators. The Commission considered that the risk of discrimination between horse-race betting operators as regards the benefits from the levy would be neutralised if the costs financed were in the common interest of all horse-race betting operators. France agreed to ensure that the levy would finance only common interest costs.

Third, there could be discrimination between horse-race betting operators as regards the obligation to pay the levy. This is because the PMU holds a monopoly on the operation of in-shop horse-race betting and also benefits from races, without actually being under an obligation to pay the parafiscal levy. The Commission considered that, as with the revenues of online horse-race betting operators – including the PMU itself, the revenues from the PMU’s monopoly on in-shop horse-race betting should also contribute to the financing of races in exactly the same way. France accepted to ensure the neutrality between in-shop and online betting. It argued that neutrality was guaranteed because the revenues from the PMU’s monopoly were in fact transferred to the horse racing and equine industry.

ii) Balancing test

With respect to the assessment directly on the basis of Article 107(3)(c), the Commission applied the balancing test [paragraphs 134-149]. More specifically, it found, first, that the measure did promote an objective of common interest. Second, that the measure was appropriate because it spread the cost of funding horse racing to all betting operators. Third, that the measure had an incentive effect because it encouraged horse racing companies to maintain their activities, given that their activities were financed by revenue from betting. This was dealt solely in two short paragraphs. Certainly it fell far below the standard of proof normally required by the Commission. The long-term negative impact of the liberalisation of online betting was a supposition. The long-term behaviour of horse racing companies verged on speculation. Fourth, because the levy could not exceed the common interest costs, the Commission concluded that the aid was proportional. But on this point, no information was provided that clearly showed that certain or all of these common costs could not be borne by the horse racing companies themselves. Lastly, the Commission found that competition would not be unduly affected because the levy applied proportionately to all European online betting companies.

Conclusions: Was there any incentive effect?

The doubts of the Commission with respect to the alleged SGEI were fully justified. The Commission was also right in requesting assurances from France that the revenue from the levy would not discriminate in favour of domestic horses, betting activities or companies. However, its conclusions on the compatibility of the aid are very dubious and debatable for the following reasons.

First, the parafiscal levy provides operating aid. Operating aid is not approved on the basis of Article 107(3)(c).

Second, the beneficiary companies do not have to do anything extra with the aid they receive [which is the definition of the incentive effect], apart from continuing with their normal operations.

Third, it is not shown that without the aid the beneficiaries would be so economically harmed that they would not be able to carry out their activities [which is another definition of the incentive effect]. Perhaps they would become more efficient or simply less profitable.

Fourth, the PMU is the largest betting company in Europe. There was no evidence that the liberalisation of the sector would reduce its revenues to the extent that horse racing companies would suffer financially.

Fifth, liberalisation could lead to loss of market share for the PMU, but it would not necessarily cause a decrease in its revenue. Liberalisation which leads to market entry of competitors also means expansion of the market and increase in overall demand. This could raise PMU’s revenue as well.

 


[1] The Commission Decision was published in the Official Journal L14 of 18/1/2014 and can be accessed at:

http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:L:2014:014:0017:0034:EN:PDF

[2] It is interesting that before the liberalization, the Commission initiated infringement proceedings against France for violation of Article 56 TFEU on free provision of services. The proceedings were terminated in 2010 with the opening of the online betting market.

Tags

About

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Related Posts

12. Oct 2021
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Security of Supply May Justify a Deviation from Public Procurement Rules - Blog visual 41

Security of Supply May Justify a Deviation from Public Procurement Rules

Security of supply justifies a deviation from the normal procurement procedures as long as the same security cannot be achieved through a competitive selection of suppliers. Introduction Point 19 of the 2012 SGEI Framework requires that the assignment of a public mission to an undertaking must comply with the applicable public procurement rules. It does not impose an obligation for […]
07. Sep 2021
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Assignment of Public Service Obligations - wordyannik mika GjFbKfI874o unsplash

Assignment of Public Service Obligations

The compensation for public service obligations may include reasonable profit and incentives for cost reduction. Introduction Member States have discretion to define services they consider to be in the general economic interest [SGEI]. However, they need to justify that definition. The Court of Justice has ruled on numerous occasions that an SGEI has “special characteristics” that set it apart from […]
25. May 2021
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides

Compensation for Universal Service Provision

As long as the compensation does not exceed the net extra costs of the universal service activities, it may be used to offset other costs. Introduction The rules on State aid for services of general economic interest [SGEI] are very generous because they allow both investment and operating aid. Yet, it is not easy to comply with those rules because […]
15. Sep 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Non-economic Activities and Services of General Economic Interest - environmental protection 683437 1280

Non-economic Activities and Services of General Economic Interest

Non-economic tasks and economic activities which are inseparable from those non-economic tasks are together, as a bundle, non-economic in nature. Public compensation for the extra costs of services of general economic interest [SGEI] may not cross-subsidise activities that fall outside the scope of the SGEI. Update on Temporary Framework: Number of approved and published covid-19 measures, as of 11 September […]
05. May 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
corona virus poster

Non-recovery of Incompatible State aid Is Costly

Legal and practical difficulties in the recovery of incompatible State aid do not constitute justifiable “absolute impossibility”. Temporary Framework On 1 May, the total number of State aid measures to combat covid-19 approved by the European Commission reached 102. Their legal basis was: Article 107(2)(b): 9; Article 107(3)(b): 86; Article 107(3)(c): 7   Introduction The 2020 Temporary Framework for State […]
27. Apr 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
corona virus poster

Identification of Undertakings in Difficulty

A company is in difficulty if, in practice, its accumulated net losses exceed 50% of its subscribed capital, regardless of whether the subscribed capital is formally written down. The classification of a company as being in difficulty is independent of the sector in which it operates and of whether a private investor would be willing to invest in it. Temporary […]
09. Apr 2020
Guest State Aid Blog by Lexxion Publisher
Woman sitting by the computer

Follow Up Webinar with Phedon Nicolaides on ‚COVID-19 and State Aid Law‘ on 20 April

The European Commission is working on quickly adapting the existing State aid legal framework to address the current Covid-19 pandemic. Join us on 20th April from the comfort and safety of your (home) office to get an insider update on the Covid-19 response by State aid experts from the European Commission and national governments. ✓ Join from wherever you are – […]
04. Feb 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
How to Compensate for the Extra Cost of Public Service Obligations: Step-by-Step Guidance on a Complex Calculation - StateAidHub blogpost5 SGEI

How to Compensate for the Extra Cost of Public Service Obligations: Step-by-Step Guidance on a Complex Calculation

The “net avoided cost methodology” takes into account only incremental costs. Introduction The two most difficult issues in the design of State aid measures to support services of general economic interest [SGEI] are the proper definition of the public service obligation [PSO] and the identification of the “counterfactual” on the basis of which the public service compensation [PSC] is calculated. […]
27. Dec 2019
State Aid Uncovered by Lexxion Publisher
5 Most Read Articles on StateAidUncovered in 2019 - 5 most read articles 2019

5 Most Read Articles on StateAidUncovered in 2019

Groundbreaking judgments like “Eesti Pagar”, applications of the private investor principle in air transport or questions of interpretation of the GBER besides many more, have moved and shaped this year’s judgments on State aid. Also Brexit and its meaning for State aid control in the UK has still been on everyone’s mind. See which articles by Prof. Phedon Nicolaides were […]
10. Dec 2019
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Retroactive Application of the GBER - m

Retroactive Application of the GBER

When an aid scheme is adjusted by limiting the eligible beneficiaries, it becomes “new” aid and must be notified to the Commission. The GBER can be applied retroactively to aid that was granted before it came into force.   Introduction In July 2016, Dilly’s Wellnesshotel wrote legal history for being the first undertaking to contest the application of the General […]