Turnover Taxes Can be Incompatible with the Internal Market

Progressive taxes levied on turnover can provide State aid that is incompatible with the internal market. Flat turnover taxes are proportional and therefore likely to be free of State aid.

 

Introduction

Hungary wanted to levy two types of turnover taxes whose purpose was to protect health. The first tax was levied on tobacco products.[1] The Commission found, in decision 2016/1846, that it provided incompatible State aid. The second tax was a charge for inspection of the food chain. The Commission, in decision 2016/1848, found that it too provided incompatible State aid.[2]

These two measures are textbook cases of what can go wrong when the objective of a tax does not match its scope of application.

1. Tax on tobacco products

The purpose of the tax was to raise revenue to improve the quality of health services and to fund treatment of diseases caused by the consumption of tobacco products. The tax was levied on all traders of tobacco products.

The tax had three features. First, it was levied on turnover in progressive increments. The lowest rate was 0.2% for turnover up to HUF 30 billion, while the highest rate was 4.5% for turnover exceeding HUF 60 billion. Second, it applied to traders whose tobacco sales exceeded 50% of their annual turnover. Third, tax liability could be reduced by up to 80% if the company concerned would make certain investments.

 

Existence of advantage

The Commission found that the tax, with its three features, conferred an advantage to smaller traders who paid a lower tax rate. The tax also conferred an advantage to those companies that made eligible investments and benefitted from an 80% reduction of their liability.

Selectivity

The reference system

As is well established, whether a tax is a selective measure is determined on the basis of a three-step test. This test requires that, first, the reference system is defined. Then, it is examined whether the tax measure in question is a derogation from the reference system. And, third, if it is derogation, it is considered whether it can be justified by the nature or general scheme of the reference system.

In order to identify the reference system, the Commission referred to the judgment of the Court of Justice in the Gibraltar case [C-106/09 P] which is probably one of the few cases where the Court attempted to define the reference system. In that case the Court said that the scope of the reference system had to be established on the basis of its objectives rather than the specific techniques it used. The Commission thought that the tobacco tax arbitrarily penalised large traders and favoured small ones. But “(32) because each company is taxed at a different rate, it is not possible for the Commission to identify one single reference rate in the health contribution.”


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

Then the Commission referred to the objective of the tax. “(33) […] The stated objective of the health contribution is to collect funds for the health care system and increase the quality of health services in Hungary in the light of the fact that smoking plays a prominent role in the development of numerous diseases and significantly contributes to increased health expenses. The Commission considers that the progressive rate structure of the health contribution does not mirror the relationship between the generation of negative effects on health by the traders and producers of tobacco products and their turnover.” In other words, the scope of the tax did not match the objective of the tax. Therefore, “(34) in the light of that objective, the Commission considers all operators subject to the health contribution to be in a comparable legal and factual situation, regardless of their level of turnover”. “(35) The reference system is therefore selective by design in a way that is not justified in the light of the objective of the health contribution, which is to collect funds for the Hungarian health system. Consequently, the appropriate reference system in the present case is the imposition of a health contribution on undertakings operating in Hungary based on their turnover, without the progressive rate structure being a part of that system.”

Derogation from the reference system

The progressive nature of the tax resulted in differentiation between undertakings on the basis of their turnover. Those with smaller turnover paid less tax.

In addition, the undertakings that made investments reduced their tax liability by up to 80%. However, the Commission thought that “(40) in the light of the intrinsic objective of the health contribution tax identified above, undertakings that have made investments and undertakings that have not made investments are in a comparable factual and legal situation, since the fact that an undertaking makes investments does nothing to reduce the negative externalities caused by smoking. Quite the contrary, the possibility of reducing an undertaking’s tax liability in the case of investments, which aims at increasing the production and trading capacity of the undertaking, appears to be inconsistent with the intrinsic objective of the health contribution tax.”

Justification

Hungary argued that the tax was justified because it penalised larger undertakings that were more able to bear the tax and which commanded more prominent market positions and acted as market leaders. The Commission rejected this argument on five grounds. First, there was no evidence linking turnover to ability to influence the market. Second, ability to pay was more closely linked to profit which was net of costs. Third, the objective of the tax to remedy health effects could be justified only by a linear turnover tax. There was no proof that an undertaking subject to the 4.5% rate caused 22 times the harm of an undertaking subject to the 0.2% rate. Fourth, the exemption from tax of those undertakings whose tobacco-related turnover was less than 50% of their total turnover contradicted the objective of limiting the impact of tobacco consumption on health. Fifth, the reduction of tax liability of up to 80% undermined the objective of the tax because it encouraged further investment by undertakings involved in trading of tobacco products.

Accordingly, the tobacco tax was State aid which was also incompatible with the internal market because it did not fall in any of the permissible categories of exception. Because Hungary had suspended the measure, the Commission did not order the recovery of the aid. If aid had to be recovered it would have to be paid back by those undertakings that were subject to tax rates lower than 4.5% and by those which benefitted from the 80% reduction of their tax liability.

2. Food-chain inspection fee

The purpose of the food-chain inspection fee was to raise revenue to cover the cost of the inspections and the operations of the Hungarian food safety agency. The fee used to be levied at a flat rate of 0.1% on the turnover of all food-chain operators. In 2014, however, the relevant law was amended so that a scale of progressive rates were introduced for stores selling “fast-moving” goods. The rates varied from 0.1% for turnover over HUF 0.5 billion to 6% for turnover exceeding HUF 300 billion. All other operators remained subject to the 0.1% fee.

Existence of advantage

The Commission found that smaller operators, with smaller turnover, benefitted from the lower rates of the fee.

Selectivity

The selectivity of a tax measure is determined according to the three-step test that defines the reference system, identifies possible derogations from the reference system and considers whether the derogations may be justified.

 

Reference system

In this case too, the Commission referred to the Gibraltar judgment [C-106/09 P] where the Court of Justice took into account the objective of the reference system in order to identify its scope of application.

The Commission could not identify a single rate as being the reference rate for the fee. However, it considered that a flat fee on turnover would have been an appropriate means of covering the cost of food inspections. Although the Commission acknowledged that “(44) […] the amount of turnover achieved by an undertaking correlates to a certain extent with the size of that undertaking, their size”, it still considered that “the objective of the food inspection fee is to finance health and safety-related checks of food as it passes through the food chain and the progressive fee structure, with rates ranging between 0% and 6%, does not mirror the relationship between the cost of inspections on the premises of the undertakings covered by the measure and their turnover.”

“(45) In light of that objective, the Commission considers all food chain operators, in general, and all operators of stores selling fast-moving consumer goods, in particular, to be in a comparable legal and factual situation, regardless of their activities or their level of turnover, and Hungary has advanced no convincing justification to discriminate between those types of undertakings when it comes to levying the food chain inspection fee. […] Hungary has therefore deliberately designed the food chain inspection fee in such a manner so as to arbitrarily favour certain undertakings, namely operators of stores selling fast-moving consumer goods with a lower level of turnover (and thus smaller undertakings), and disadvantage others, namely larger undertakings, which also tend to be foreign-owned.”

“(46) The reference system is therefore selective by design in a way that is not justified in light of the objective of the food inspection fee, which is to finance health and safety-related checks of food as it passes through the food chain. Consequently, the appropriate reference system in the present case is the imposition of an inspection fee on food chain undertakings operating in Hungary based on their turnover, without the progressive fee structure being a part of that system.”

Derogation from the reference system

The food inspection fee derogated from the reference system because “(49) […] the progressive fee structure […] differentiates between undertakings in a comparable factual and legal situation as regards the objective of the food inspection fee based on their activities and their size.”

Justification

Hungary argued that the progressive nature of the food inspection fee was justified on the grounds that more resources and time were necessary for the inspection of larger undertakings. The Commission rejected this argument for the following reasons.

First, the Commission conceded that in principle a progressive fee would be justified if the inspection costs and food risk associated with larger undertakings increased more than proportionately with their turnover. However, no evidence had been provided to support the more than proportionate increase of the fee. The difference between the lowest and the highest rate was more than 60 times. In fact, a moment’s reflection would suggest that the opposite is likely to be true. There are likely to be economies of scale in the process of inspecting larger undertakings and, therefore, considerable savings per unit of inspection, as expressed in time or number of officials.

Second, there was no evidence that the inspection costs or risks associated with sellers of “fast-moving” goods were larger than the costs or risks associated with sellers of other foods with equivalent turnover.

The inevitable conclusion was that the food inspection fee was selective, it granted aid to operators subject to fees lower than 6% and that it was incompatible with the internal market. However, no recovery was ordered because Hungary had suspended the measure when the Commission opened the formal investigation procedure.

Conclusions

Both of the Hungarian measures demonstrate the problems that can arise when the method and scope of application of a tax deviate from the avowed objective of the tax. In these two cases, the avowed objective was to promote health and fund inspections. However, in practice the tobacco tax and inspection fee affected disproportionately larger operators. Larger operators are likely to be foreign operators. Perhaps the true intention was to make it more difficult for foreign companies to establish and operate in Hungary. But it must be said that the Commission decisions provide no evidence that indeed that was the intention of the two measures. At any rate, Member States must always consider the likely impact of their taxes because State aid rules apply to public measures according to their effects rather than their methods or intentions.

———————————————————-

[1] The full text of the decision is published in the Official Journal, OJ L282, 19/10/2016, and it can be accessed at:

http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=uriserv:OJ.L_.2016.282.01.0043.01.ENG&toc=OJ:L:2016:282:TOC.

[2] The full text of the decision is published in the Official Journal, OJ, L282, 19/10/2016, and it can be accessed at:

http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=uriserv:OJ.L_.2016.282.01.0063.01.ENG&toc=OJ:L:2016:282:TOC.

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

14. Mrz 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides

State Aid for the Resolution of a Polish bank

Introduction Whenever a bank seeks State aid, it must be considered as “failing or likely to fail”. A failing bank must be liquidated or resolved. Resolution means that the critical functions of the bank are preserved while the rest are wound down. Critical functions are those that impact significantly the real economy such as deposits, loans to SMEs or payments. […]
07. Mrz 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides

Tax Advantages and Competitive Bidding

Introduction Award of contracts or sale of state assets through competitive bidding procedures or tenders are presumed to result in a market prices and to confer no advantage to the winner in the meaning of Article 107(1) TFEU. However, on 25 January 2023, the General Court ruled, in case T-666/21, Società Navigazione Siciliana v European Commission, that certain tax advantages […]
28. Feb 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides

Discretion of Public Authorities and Selectivity

Introduction On 2 February 2023, the Court of justice, in case C649/20 P, Spain and Others v European Commission, clarified the extent to which public authorities can implement general measures without in practice favouring any undertaking. The exercise of administrative discretion can turn a general measure into selective. The Court made a distinction between what may be called “related” or […]
21. Feb 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides

The Selectivity and Profitability of Agreements between Airports and Airlines

Introduction Selectivity is a tricky issue. Even a measure that appears not to favour or exclude any undertaking may in practice prove to be selective if its effects favour certain undertakings over others that are in a comparable situation. In order to determine whether they are comparable it necessary to examine the objective of the measure. This is what the […]
17. Jan 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides

The Private Acquirer Test: An Illuminating and also Puzzling Judgment

A public authority may act as a market operator and acquire services through a private third party without conferring an advantage to the provider of those services. Introduction When a public authority buys a service and pays the market price it does not confer an advantage to the seller in the meaning of Article 107(1) TFEU. Even if it pursues […]
10. Jan 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides

The Value of Land

Different valuation methods do not confer a selective advantage if they generate similar results. Introduction Land or immovable property has no intrinsic value. Its value depends on how the land or property is used. In turn, how it is used is determined by several factors such as its location, and the applicable zoning rules. A plot of land in an […]
22. Nov 2022
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides

The “Arm’s Length Principle” and the Taxation of Transactions between Related Companies

The arm’s length principle is not an autonomous principle that can be applied to any advance tax ruling. It must be provided in the national tax system. Furthermore, the arm’s length principle must be applied, if it exists in the national tax system, in the form that is defined by that tax system. Introduction In a series of decisions beginning […]
18. Okt 2022
von Phedon Nicolaides

Public Authorities Acting as Private Investors

It is a well-established principle in the case law that when a public authority acts as a private investor, it must disregard all public policy objectives and its obligations as an arm of the state. Many judgments of EU courts and Commission decisions have examined in detail the various elements that underpin the reasoning of a private investor such as […]
11. Okt 2022
von Phedon Nicolaides

Selectivity of Regional Schemes

Introduction Article 107(3)(a) areas and the outermost regions of the EU [defined in Article 349 TFEU] are more favourably treated under State aid rules. But they still have to comply with the terms of Commission authorising decisions. In case regional State aid is found to be incompatible with the internal market, their regional handicaps cannot justify any leniency in the […]
06. Sep 2022
State Aid Unciovered von Phedon Nicolaides

Special Economic Zones

Member States must check that the State aid claimed by undertakings established in special economic zones concern activities that are actually carried out within those zones. Introduction Several Member States have special economic zones in which companies enjoy preferential tax treatment. These zones can be divided into two categories: those that can be found mostly in the new Member States […]