Disruptions vs refusals of supply: a guide to the case law

Disruptions vs refusals of supply: a guide to the case law - 4

On 31 March 2022, FTC Chair Lina Khan was visiting her counterparts in Brussels. She also spoke at the CRA Conference, describing the need for new tools to tackle new problems: ‘[Practices] can still facilitate the maintenance of a monopoly—and therefore be illegal—but the precise mechanism may look different from some of the traditional concepts that antitrust enforcers look to.’ Khan zoomed in on one example:

[A]s the FTC noted in its antitrust lawsuit against Facebook, the imperative to scale quickly and build a large user base can lead a platform to encourage and lure third parties to interconnect with its network, only to later impose restrictive conditions or cut them off entirely. This type of ‘open first, closed later’ scheme does not quite fit a traditional ‘refusal to deal’ framework, and the tactic can be anticompetitive even if the platform did not have a duty to deal.

In economic terms, the notion of ‘open early, closed later’ isn’t new: in 2005 already (and based on even earlier work), Shapiro testified that ‘[t]he most troublesome cases arise when the dominant firm appears to be following a strategy of “open early, closed late.”’

For example, in a network industry, a firm might obtain a dominant position based in part on certain ‘open’ policies that induce reliance by complementary firms, and then later exploit that position by offering less favorable interconnection terms or by refusing to interconnect with them altogether.

While ‘open early, closed late’ is still a new-ish term, the European Commission (EC) and courts have long treated such cases differently, distinguishing disruptions of supply from first-time (‘de novo’) refusals to supply. However, the case law has been rather muddled. In this blog post, I trace the origins of the disruption of supply case law. The underlying question is whether disruptions of supply are different enough from refusals to merit separate standards.

From Commercial Solvents to Bronner

The Commercial Solvents judgment (1974), which marked the start of the refusal to supply case law, concerned a disruption of supply. Commercial Solvents (CS) had been supplying Zoja with Aminobutanol—a raw material required to manufacture the medicine Ethambutol—for five years. After CS started manufacturing Ethambutol itself, it stopped supplying Zoja with Aminobutanol. Substituting Aminobutanol for another raw material would resource-intensive and in any case experimental. The European Court of Justice (ECJ) confirmed the EC decision finding the disruption of supply abusive:

[A]n undertaking which has a dominant position in the market in raw materials and which, with the object of reserving such raw material for manufacturing its own derivatives, refuses to supply a customer, which is itself a manufacturer of these derivatives, and therefore risks eliminating all competition on the part of this customer, is abusing its dominant position[.]

Thus, the judgment already implicitly examined the indispensability of the input and explicitly put forward the required anticompetitive effects (risk of eliminating all competition).

Télémarketing (1985) concerned a similar scenario. Centre Belge had been conducting telemarketing operations on the Belgian television station RTL (which held a legal monopoly) via Information Publicité—RTL’s exclusive agent for television advertising. After two years, Information Publicité notified advertisers it would no longer accept any telemarketing except its own. In its preliminary ruling, the ECJ cited Commercial Solvents in holding that:

[A]n abuse within the meaning of article [102] is committed where, without any objective necessity, an undertaking holding a dominant position on a particular market reserves to itself or to an undertaking belonging to the same group an ancillary activity which might be carried out by another undertaking as part of its activities on a neighbouring but separate market[.]

The ECJ explicitly referred to the indispensable nature of the input (telemarketing airtime) and the elimination of all competition, as well as the possibility of technical or commercial justifications.

In United Brands (1978)—adopted between Commercial Solvents and Télémarketing—the ECJ took a different approach. United Brands (UB) had stopped providing Chiquita bananas to Olesen—‘one of [its] most important long standing customers’ in Denmark. In a section dedicated to the ‘refusal to continue supplies’, the ECJ asserted positively that:

[A]n undertaking in a dominant position for the purpose of marketing a product … cannot stop supplying a long standing customer who abides by regular commercial practice, if the orders placed by that customer are in no way out of the ordinary.

The ECJ found such conduct inconsistent with Article 102(b) TFEU in that it limits markets to the prejudice of consumers and with Article 102(c) as it amounts to discrimination liable to eliminate a trading partner from the market. In this case, however, the firm halting supplies was not entering the downstream market. Rather, UB referred to the fact that Olesen had participated in an advertising campaign for competing Dole bananas. While the ECJ recognized a firm may protect its commercial interests, it considered UB’s action disproportionate.

When the ECJ crystallized its doctrine in the Magill (1995) and Bronner (1998), two cases of de novo refusal, it relied on Commercial Solvents and Télémarketing—not United Brands—for precedent. The ECJ established a clear refusal to supply test, requiring ‘exceptional circumstances’ and in particular (i) a refusal to supply an indispensable input (upstream); (ii) likely to eliminate all competition in an adjacent market (downstream); (iii) not justified by objective considerations (when the refusal concerns IP rights, the refusal must also prevent the appearance of a new product).

Microsoft

Until the 2000s, the distinction between disruptions and refusals to supply did not play a major role. It may have influenced case selection, with the EC prioritizing cases of disruption, but the number of cases is too small to draw firm conclusions. United Brands appeared, if not an aberration, at least a rarity.

In Microsoft I (2004), the EC assessed Microsoft’s refusal to provide interoperability information to Sun Microsystems and other developers of workgroup server operating systems. More specifically, the refusal constituted a disruption: disclosures that Microsoft undertook with respect to Windows NT had been discontinued with the development of Windows 2000.  The EC argued that the list of exceptional circumstances to be taken into account when assessing a refusal to supply should not be exhaustive. It pointed out how, in Commercial Solvents and Télémarketing, ‘the European Courts have given weight to circumstances where a refusal to supply constituted a disruption of previous levels of supply’. The EC also detailed the rationale between Microsoft’s diminished interoperability, namely an ‘open early, closed late’ strategy:

The value that their products brought to the network also augmented the client PC operating systems’ value in the customers’ eyes and therefore Microsoft—as long as it did not have a credible work group server operating system alternative—had incentives to have its client PC operating system interoperate with non-Microsoft work group server operating systems. While entering the work group server operating system market, pledging support for already established technologies was important in gaining a foothold and the confidence of the customers. Once Microsoft’s work group server operating system gained acceptance in the market, however, Microsoft’s incentives changed and holding back access to information relating to interoperability with the Windows environment started to make sense.

Nevertheless, the EC went on to prove that Microsoft’s conduct fulfilled the more stringent test for de novo refusals. On appeal, the EC clarified that it treated the disruption of supply ‘not as an abuse in itself but as one factor relevant to the assessment of Microsoft’s refusal to supply’. At the hearing, it elaborated that the disruption was one of three factors allowing Microsoft’s conduct to be characterized as abusive. However, the General Court (GC) too ended up applying the Bronner/Magill test. It has been suggested that the remedy, which required Microsoft to document and share a great deal of interoperability information, may have justified the higher standard.

EC guidance

In between its Microsoft decision and the appeal judgment, the EC took the opportunity to reflect on the standards guiding the application of Article 102 TFEU, which resulted in a Discussion Paper (2005). The paper is remarkable for its clear distinction between ‘termination of an existing supply relationship’ and ‘refusal to start supplying an input’, arguing the former should be subject to less stringent standards than the latter. The three main reasons to uphold stringent standards for de novo refusals do not apply (to the same extent) in case of disruptions. Firstly, duties to deal decrease the dominant firm’s incentives to invest into building essential facilities—if they are forced to share them, they may not get an adequate return on investment. This is different for disruptions of supply:

That the dominant company in the past has found it in its interest to supply an input to one or more customers shows that the dominant company at a certain point in time considered it efficient to engage in such supply relationships. This and the fact that its customers are likely to have made investments connected to these supply relationships create a rebuttable presumption that continuing these relationships is pro-competitive.

Secondly, duties to deal interfere with the dominant firm’s fundamental freedom of contract, but that freedom is not equally imperiled in cases where the dominant firm has already chosen to contract. Thirdly, it is challenging to design duty to deal remedies, but previous dealing facilitates the exercise by serving as a benchmark—the competition authority or court does not have to start from nothing when setting access conditions.

For those reasons, the EC proposed a less stringent standard for disruptions, namely a ‘likely market distorting effect’. The impact on the level of competition in the market depends mainly on the pre-existing level of competition in the downstream market and whether the dominant upstream firm is active in that market. For instance, ‘if the input owner is itself active in the downstream market and terminates supplies to one of its few competitors, it will normally be presumed that there is a negative effect on competition on the downstream market.’

In the EC’s subsequent Guidance Paper (2009), however, little remained of the distinction. On the contrary, the EC held that the Bronner conditions apply to both disruptions of previous supply and de novo refusals. It did note that ‘the termination of an existing supply arrangement is more likely to be found to be abusive than a de novo refusal to supply’, especially in view of relation-specific investments made by co-contractors and the fact that previous supply indicates the dominant firm was receiving adequate compensation for its investment. Thus a light reversal of the burden of proof remains justified: the EC states that—in such cases of disruption—‘[i]t would therefore be up to the dominant company to demonstrate why circumstances have actually changed in such a way that the continuation of its existing supply relationship would put in danger its adequate compensation.’

The return of United Brands

Just before publication of the Guidance Paper, the ECJ got another opportunity to rule on disruptions of supply. In Sot. Lélos (2008), it was asked for guidance in proceedings brought by pharmaceutical wholesalers against GlaxoSmithKline’s Greek subsidiary (GSK). After years of fulfilling orders, GSK had halted supplies, which wholesalers distributed on the Greek market and in other Member States (sometimes in competition with GSK). Referencing Commercial Solvents and United Brands, the ECJ held:

The established case-law of the Court shows that the refusal by an undertaking occupying a dominant position on the market of a given product to meet the orders of an existing customer constitutes abuse of that dominant position under Article [102] where, without any objective justification, that conduct is liable to eliminate a trading party as a competitor[.]

It is important to ascertain whether the orders are not out of the ordinary, but if not, a lower standard of anticompetitiveness (liable to eliminate a trading party as competitor) applies. However, it must be noted that GSK’s disruption of supply was aimed impeding parallel trade by wholesalers. Given EU competition law’s unique market integration goal, parallel trade enjoys special protection, which may explain the lower standard applied in this case.

Preliminary conclusion

Disruptions of supply are a suitable qualification for the ‘open early, closed late’ scenarios often observed in the digital economy. The case law, however, allows for more than one reading. On the one hand, one could rely on United Brands and (to a lesser extent) Sot. Lélos to argue a less stringent standard applies to disruptions. On the other hand, one can write these two cases off as aberrations in an otherwise clear framework that requires indispensability/elimination of all competition for every refusal, be it of established supply or de novo. In the 2000s, even the EC stopped seriously differentiating the two, so any clarification may have to be led by the European courts. In fact, such clarification is starting to appear, first with Slovak Telekom and then Google Shopping (see Section III.C.3 of this paper of mine for a discussion). While the reasons for a differentiated treatment of disruptions vs refusals are sound, its foundations in the case law are still rather shaky.

.

This blog post first appeared on the Maastricht University Law Blog, in anticipation of #COMIPinDigiMarkts2022.

Tags

About

Friso Bostoen

Blog Editor

Assistant Professor of Competition Law and Digital Regulation, Tilburg University

Friso Bostoen is an assistant professor of competition law and digital regulation at Tilburg University. Previously, he was a Max Weber Fellow at the European University Institute. He holds degrees from KU Leuven (PhD, LLM) and Harvard University (LLM). Friso’s research focuses on antitrust enforcement in digital markets. His work has resulted in numerous international publications, presentations, and awards (including the AdC Competition Policy Award 2019 and the Concurrences PhD Award 2022). In addition, Friso edits the CoRe Blog and hosts the Monopoly Attack podcast.

>> Friso’s CoRe Blog posts >>

Related Posts

16. Nov 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
platforms, dma, gatekeepers, digital markets act, apple, google, microsoft, smasung

Rebutting the gatekeeper status – what does it take?

The deadline for appeals on the gatekeeper designation under the DMA is nearing its end.  Since the DMA imposes gatekeepers with demanding obligations, it is only natural that the potential subjects of this regulation will attempt to contest this status. What remains, however, to be clarified is what prospective gatekeepers can put forward as evidence to avoid being designated as […]
12. Sep 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
Microsoft teams antitrust claim, abuse of dominance, European commission

Microsoft III – Paving The Way To A Tying Trilogy?

This summer the European commission (finally) announced it will start a formal investigation against Microsoft following Slack’s complaint concerning the (abusive) tying or bundling or Teams to the Microsoft and Office 365 suites. Not long after, Microsoft came out with an official statement concerning the changes in its pricing and distribution strategy  of Teams it will introduce in order to […]
18. Jan 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, refusal to supply, Lithuanian railways, bronner, essential facility, art. 102 TFEU

Case C-42/21P Lithuanian Railways – another clarification on the Bronner case law and the non-exhaustive character of art. 102 TFEU

The recent case of Lithuanian Railways provides yet another clarification on the scope of application of the Bronner case law. The Judgement of the CJEU reconfirms exceptional character of the Bronner case law and the type of situations it is intended to apply to. By doing so the CJEU potentially helps prevent future disputes of a similar  nature in the […]
03. Jan 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
facebook, competition law, abuse of dominance, art. 102 TFEU, multisided platforms, dominant position, tying and bundling, unfair trading conditions, competition economics, european commission,

On-platform Tying or Another Case of Leveraging- A Discussion on Facebook Marketplace

Just before 2022 ended the Commission sent a statement of objections to Meta regarding the potential abusive behaviour of Facebook. According to the statement of objections, Facebook may be engaging in (i) abusive tying practices with regard to Facebook Marketplace as users (i.e. consumers) that log into Facebook and are automatically also offered access to the Facebook Marketplace, without the […]
06. Apr 2021
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, art. 102 tfeu, online platforms, data sharing, refusal to supply

Online platforms and the essential facility doctrine – a status update following Slovak Telekom and the DMA

The recent judgment of the CJEU in Slovak Telekom provides important guidance on the application of the Bronner case law in cases concerning abusive market access obstacles. Such guidance is of particular value in the context of online platforms, where issues of access have been considered being unsolvable because of the stringent criteria of the refusal to supply case law. […]
03. Dec 2020
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
Why you (often) don’t need the essential facility doctrine in the digital economy? – Interpreting Lithuanian Railways and Slovak Telekom - problem 4612945 1280

Why you (often) don’t need the essential facility doctrine in the digital economy? – Interpreting Lithuanian Railways and Slovak Telekom

The insights from Lithuanian Railways and Slovak Telekom may have serious implications for the application of the Oscar Bronner case law in the future. These insights may prove, however, to have the most value in the digital economy where it would appear that the essential facility doctrine might often not even be needed – not even in the case of […]
04. Sep 2020
Features by Friso Bostoen
Epic, Fortnite, Apple, battle royale, competition law, antitrust, district court, monopolization, monopoly, essential facilities, refusal to supply, tying, abuse of dominance

Epic v Apple (1): introducing antitrust’s latest Big Tech battle royale

Mid-August 2020, a series of events unfolded in a short period of time. They may prove a watershed moment for the role of antitrust in regulating digital markets. It started when gamers playing Fortnite on their iPhone were suddenly faced with a new choice screen when buying in-app currency: What changed is that Epic, the developer of Fortnite, introduced an […]
27. Aug 2020
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
Slack v. Microsoft – more than just another tying case - microsoft 4417280 1280

Slack v. Microsoft – more than just another tying case

The recent wave of claims against digital giants appears to have completed a circle with Slack’s recent claim against Microsoft for allegedly abusing its dominant position by tying Microsoft Teams to the Office 365 software package. One cannot deny the resemblance between this claim and the previous tying cases Microsoft had faced, however, upon closer look Slack’s claim is much […]
04. Feb 2020
Features by Liesbet Van Acker
The Intermarché-Coca Cola dispute: Who’s the bad guy? An analysis of the retail distributor-supplier relationship - beverages 3105631 1920 1 825x400 1

The Intermarché-Coca Cola dispute: Who’s the bad guy? An analysis of the retail distributor-supplier relationship

If you want to buy Coca Cola products in the supermarket Intermarché in France, you will arrive home empty-handed. Since the end of December, Coca Cola has refused to refill Intermarché’s stock, following a conflict about Intermarché’s unwillingness to sell the whole assortment of Coca Cola’s products. In the summer, Intermarché communicated to Coca Cola that it would like to […]
12. Nov 2019
Features by Friso Bostoen
online shopping cartoon

Amazon cases on the move: Bundeskartellamt closes proceedings while European Commission opens formal investigation

The 17th of July has been quite the day for Amazon, at least when it comes to antitrust. Firstly, the German Competition Authority (Bundeskartellamt) has closed its abuse of dominance proceedings against Amazon in return for concessions from the online marketplace. Secondly, the European Commission announced that it was opening a formal investigation into possible anti-competitive conduct by Amazon. This blog post takes a closer […]

Subscribe to our newsletter to be regularly informed about our upcoming conferences, Lexxion Trainings, on-the-spot workshops and updates on Lexxion’s publications.

Don’t miss the news by signing up for our free newsletters. Sign up now!