Webtaxi: The Luxembourg Competition Authority exempts an algorithmic price-fixing arrangement on efficiency grounds

Webtaxi: The Luxembourg Competition Authority exempts an algorithmic price-fixing arrangement on efficiency grounds - drive

With the increasing digitalization of economy, algorithms are more and more often relied on by businesses in their economic activities for many purposes including setting prices. Competition authorities have concerns that the use of algorithmic pricing may result in undertakings coordinating their pricing policies to the detriment of competition (see here, here and here).
The decision recently handed down by the ‘Conseil de la Concurrence’ or the Luxembourg Competition Authority (thereinafter LCA) in Webtaxi illustrates, instead, a pro-competitive use of pricing algorithms. This case involved an agreement under which several taxi operators jointly determined the fares for taxi services via an automated algorithm. Notwithstanding its nature of a serious competition breach, the LCA eventually exempted the agreement due to the expected efficiency gains resulting from the use of the algorithm.

The Webtaxi platform

Webtaxi is a booking platform for taxi services in Luxembourg that was created in June 2015. Prospective clients can book their taxis by phone, a mobile app or a website. By means of a geo-localization functionality Webtaxi matches each booking request to the nearest taxi driver to the position of waiting clients. Taxi operators pay Webtaxi a monthly fee for using its booking services whereas the platform determines the fares that taxi drivers should apply to clients.
The LCA opened an antitrust investigation against Webtaxi following the receipt of a complaint filed by a competing taxi operator. Article 7(4) of the Law of 23 October 2011 (LCL) states that a new case is assigned by an order made by the President of the LCA to a member of the LCA, the appointed councillor. The appointed councillor is responsible for conducting the necessary investigations and, eventually, drafting the statement of objection to be put forward before the Council of the LCA that adjudicates on the alleged competition breach.

Initially (and until 3 February 2017), Webtaxi, or more precisely ProCab as it was previously known, only recommended a maximum price. Taxi drivers and customers were then free to negotiate the fares within the upper limits set by Webtaxi. The appointed councilor considered that this practice constituted an anti-competitive horizontal agreement prohibited by Article 3 of the Luxembourg Competition Law of 23 October 2011 (LCL) corresponding to Article 101(1) TFEU. Yet, because it led to efficiency gains also to the benefit of customers, in terms of more accessible and quicker taxi services, the agreement in question qualified for the individual exemption in Article 4 LCL, which is equivalent to Article 101(3) TFEU. The findings of the appointed councilor were not challenged by the parties and were then accepted by the LCA.

The decision of the Luxembourg Competition Authority

However, the pricing model that Webtaxi has been applying since 3 February 2017 required a more careful examination from the LCA. According to this newer pricing model Webtaxi automatically calculates the fares with an algorithm factoring in several parameters: price per kilometer; distance and travelling time of taxi rides; and traffic condition. The algorithmic fares are fixed and bind both taxi drivers and customers who are not allowed to negotiate them.
Considering the intermediation function between taxi drivers and prospective clients carried out by Webtaxi, the LCA qualified the platform as a two-sided market: it comprises not only the relations between Webtaxi and the participating taxi operators but also the relations between taxi operators and clients. Under the umbrella of the platform, the taxi operators agreed to jointly determine the fares for the taxi rides assigned by Webtaxi via the algorithmic pricing tool. That said, the LCA acknowledged that even restrictive agreements are not prohibited per se as they may still be justified under Article 4 LCL. Therefore, the LCA assessed whether the Webtaxi agreement met the four-limb test in Article 4 LCL. For an agreement to be exempted in accordance with this provision, it must satisfy four cumulative conditions: i) the agreement brings about economic efficiencies; ii) a fair share of those benefits accrues to consumers; iii) the agreement is indispensable, necessary and proportionate to achieve the efficiencies; iv) the agreement does not eliminate competition in the relevant market.

a) The condition for the improvement of economic efficiency

 Webtaxi provided proof of multiple efficiency gains resulting from the agreement that were accepted by the LCA. First, by relying on geo-localization to assign clients to the closest taxi drivers, Webtaxi reduced the number of empty taxi rides. Second, this more efficient allocation of resources cut pollution caused by taxis, contributing to combat the greenhouse effect. Third, clients enjoyed a uniform, centralized and wider offer of taxi services on a 24/7 basis. Fourth, Webtaxi allowed taxi operators to more efficiently adapt supply to demand in peak and off-peak hours. Fifth, the LCA considered that the customer confidence in being able to use the booking services offered by Webtaxi should add value to the taxi industry in Luxembourg.

b) The condition of fair share for consumers

A fair share of efficiency gains in the form of quantitative and qualitative benefits accrued to taxi users. The quantitative benefits are mainly expected from the algorithmic pricing used by Webtaxi. In what is, probably, the most interesting passage of the decision, the LCA observed that reliance on a pricing algorithm, based on neutral and objective factors, enabled taxi operators to offer less expensive rides. Upon the receipt of a booking request, the algorithm calculates the applicable fares which is immediately communicated to the client. The algorithm price must be equal or lower than that indicated on the taximeter of the chosen taxi driver so to enable customers to compare the two prices. Moreover, the algorithm applies degressive fares decreasing as travelling distance increases. As a result, the algorithmic pricing may lead to a substantive reduction in the taxi fares paid for by customers.
The Webtaxi platform was also credited for qualitative benefits. First, as hinted above, the use of the geo-localizsation app reduced waiting times of customers at the pick-up points as well as the number of empty taxi rides. Second, by regrouping several Luxembourg-based taxi operators, Webtaxi increased the number of taxi drivers ensuring 24/7 taxi services to prospective clients. Third, the LCA believed that a fair share of the gains resulting from lowering the atmospheric pollution caused by taxis might accrue to clients.

c) The indispensability condition

Contrary to what was held by the appointed councilor, the LCA found that Webtaxi met this condition. Indeed, the application of the fixed uniform algorithm-calculated fares was instrumental in ensuring the correct working of the Webtaxi reservation center. It was exactly the algorithmic pricing that allows to match customers with the closest taxi drivers. The major interest of customers in using Webtaxi was to have a given price for a given taxi ride fixed in advance. In absence of the algorithmic uniform pricing, taxi drivers and clients should individually negotiate the applicable fares. Consequently, the likely outcome in such cases is that the taxi drivers eventually chosen by the clients because of the lower fares might not be the one identified by the geo-localization app. Under such circumstances the viability of the Webtaxi business model may be undermined because all the gains generated by the geo-localization system are unlikely to materialize.
A further advantage conferred by Webtaxi to customers is to shield the latter from the risks inherent in taxi rides, namely fare increases resulting from unexpected events. Such risks are entirely borne by the taxi operators as in case of traffic jams that stretch travelling times without customers having to face a fare increase. Again, had Webtaxi not applied the pricing algorithm a portion of such risks might have been translated to customers.
For all these reasons, the LCA concluded that the algorithmic pricing arrangement was necessary to ensure the correct working of Webtaxi. Though the challenged practice amounted to a competition restraint by object, there were no viable alternatives with the same pro-competitive effects.

d) The condition of the preservation of competition

This limb of the test requires an assessment of the competition impact of the contested agreement. The LCA estimated that only 26% of the taxis operating in Luxembourg participated in the Webtaxi platform. For this reason, the LCA ruled out that the price-fixing agreement under investigation had substantially harmed the health of competition in the relevant market.
Eventually the LCA authorized the restrictive agreement concluded between competing taxi operators examined in Webtaxi. In spite of its nature of a competition restraint by object, the agreement met all the cumulative conditions set out in Article 4 LCL. Therefore, the LCA granted the Article 4 LCL individual exemption and closed proceedings with a non-infringement decision.

Conclusion

The old adage that good things come in smaller packages fits well in Webtaxi. Though the decision was about the legality of a pricing model applied by platform for the booking of local taxi’s, it is worth reading for a manyifold reasons.
First, Webtaxi is the first case in which the LCA granted an individual exemption to a horizontal anticompetitive agreement pursuant to Article 4 LCL. Second, it is one of the rare cases in which an acting competition authority has granted an individual exemption to a serious competition breach, such as a price fixing practice (see, for example, AirFrance/Alitalia and Reims II) . Third, the LCA opted for a broader approach in the interpretation of the concept of the efficiency gains looking also at non-competition factors. In addition to the lowering of the taxis fares, the LCA pointed to the reduction of the environmental footprint of the activities of the taxi operators that would have positive repercussions on customers’ health (examples of agreements breaching Article 101(1) TFEU but eventually cleared by the European Commission according to Article 101(3) TFEU also on environmental grounds can be found in Exxon/Shell; European Council of Manufacturers of Domestic Appliances (CECED). Interestingly, in Utopia the LCA also relied on non-competition factors in the context of an antitrust investigation into a concentration between two movie theatres). Fourth, the LCA correctly applied an effects-based approach when assessing the competition impact of the Webtaxi’s algorithmic pricing. Taking into account the objective nature of the parameters factored in by the algorithm, the LCA arrived at the conclusion that the examined algorithmic pricing is not conducive to a price collusion. Rather, it has a pro-competitive nature favoring a more efficient mode of provision of taxi services at lower costs for customers. It should be borne in mind, however, that the feared anti-competitive effects of the agreement were rather limited. This is also, partly, due to the fact that the combined market shares of the taxi operators using the Webtaxi booking services were well below the 30% threshold over which an agreement may be presumed to negatively affect competition.

In conclusion, the takeaway lesson from Webtaxi is that, notwithstanding the growing concerns of competition authorities that see them as conducing to price collusion, pricing algorithms may also be pro-competitive. That said, Webtaxi should be read with the caveat that the LCA determined it on the basis only of national competition provisions. Because the Luxembourg taxi sector is governed by national regulation and taxi services do not affect trade between Member States, the agreement in question was outside the reach of Article 101 TFEU.

Tags

About

Michele Giannino

Michele is an Italian qualified lawyer. He holds a LLM in European Law from University of Leicester and also gained a PHD in Competition Law at the Queen Mary of University of London defending a thesis on the regulation of transnational mergers. Active researcher on competitin and IP law, he advises clients on civil and business law.

Leave a Reply

Related Posts

07. Nov 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
app store, apple, abuse of dominance, platforms, ACM, art. 102 TFEU.

The ACM vs. Apple AppStore – A Second Chance To Get It Right

The Dutch case concerning the Apple App Store appears to make a (welcome) comeback. The case that started in 2019 came to a rather disappointing end in the summer of 2022 when the Dutch competition authority issued a public statement that gave the impression that it was satisfied with Apple’s adjustments to the App Store front in the Netherlands. This […]
09. Dec 2020
Features by Martyn Dobbin
Algorithmic Code

Pricing algorithms and competition: what competitive concerns do pricing algorithms raise?

Introduction Through Big Data and increasing digitalisation of commerce, algorithmic pricing (AP) has become a staple of markets globally. While this increased prevalence has produced a multitude of procompetitive market outcomes – for example, increased supply-side and demand-side efficiencies – there exists palpable academic and administrative concern that AP may greater facilitate the emergence of collusion in digital markets. In […]
06. Apr 2020
Features by Rita Paukste
EURIBOR Cartel: Features of Collusion and Detection of Cartel - skyscraper

EURIBOR Cartel: Features of Collusion and Detection of Cartel

A colleague of mine (kudos for you know who you are) once told me that in his competition law class he has a part called “how to make a good cartel?” A thought-provoking academic exercise in many aspects, indeed. When analyzing cartels in the financial sector this popped in mind to raise other questions – how participants in cartels in […]
29. Nov 2018
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
Apple’s App Store commission fee and (anti-competitive) governance: when a platform’s zero-pricing strategy becomes expensive - app store

Apple’s App Store commission fee and (anti-competitive) governance: when a platform’s zero-pricing strategy becomes expensive

These days Apple is at the Supreme Court trying to defend its pricing scheme for the App Store, which is currently under fire for being potentially abusive with respect consumers that end up paying perhaps quite a bit more for their apps than they should. Although it is uncertain whether the claimants will be allowed to proceed with the claim, […]
18. Oct 2018
Features by Michiel Verhulst
The BritNed v ABB Case: private enforcement pur sang - jonny caspari d2HWQg82RUo unsplash

The BritNed v ABB Case: private enforcement pur sang

Private enforcement of competition law, particularly with regard to cartel damages claims, has been a highly debated topic since the seminal ECJ decision Courage v Crehan in 2001 (e.g. here and here). Together with the Netherlands and Germany, the UK is traditionally put forward as one of the main fora to introduce a damages action based on a competition law infringement. However, it was only […]
07. Aug 2018
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
Price monitoring software and competition – new possibilities for RPM in absence of sufficient deterrence - coding 1853305 1280

Price monitoring software and competition – new possibilities for RPM in absence of sufficient deterrence

Shortly after the dropping the A-bomb on Google for its alleged tying practices, the Commission imposed fines of over €111 million on Asus, Denon & Marantz, Philips and Pioneer for fixing the minimum resale prices of their online retailers. This recent case shows that the Commission is serious about taking on competition law infringements in the online sphere, however, it […]
17. Jul 2018
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
Tales of two-sided markets, market definitions and anti-competitive effects - insights from Ohio v. American Express - ryan born 16317 unsplash

Tales of two-sided markets, market definitions and anti-competitive effects – insights from Ohio v. American Express

  The case of Ohio v. Amex is the final phase of a long legal battle that started back in 2010 where Amex was accused of infringing section 1 of the Sherman Act for imposing its anti-steering provisions on merchants accepting Amex. While not delivering on all fronts, the case of Amex is an important one in the context of […]
07. Jun 2018
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
When Algorithmic Pricing meets Concerted Practices- the case of Partneo - emile guillemot zegxcRu2f4E unsplash

When Algorithmic Pricing meets Concerted Practices- the case of Partneo

Algorithmic collusion, algorithmic cartels, AI price fixing cartels and many other pseudo computer science themes have become a source of great interest for competition law authorities, practitioners and academics. The allure of these topics is understandable; the idea that cartels can come into existence without human intervention is a fascinating matter despite the fact that fully automated (not to mention […]
15. Mar 2018
Features by Friso Bostoen
Can consumers pay too much when they pay nothing? The Bundeskartellamt’s Facebook case - kon karampelas HUBofEFQ6CA unsplash 1

Can consumers pay too much when they pay nothing? The Bundeskartellamt’s Facebook case

Can consumers pay too much when they pay nothing? The question might seem absurd, but a recent investigation by the Bundeskartellamt raises the question: it is accusing Facebook, which offers its services for free, of an infringement that looks a lot like excessive pricing. In this blog post, I unpack the Facebook case by explaining the social network’s business model, […]

Subscribe to our newsletter to be regularly informed about our upcoming conferences, Lexxion Trainings, on-the-spot workshops and updates on Lexxion’s publications.

Don’t miss the news by signing up for our free newsletters. Sign up now!