Repayable Advances for Support of Research Projects

Repayable Advances for Support of Research Projects - StateAidHub blogpost34 RDI GBER

The amount of State aid in a repayable advance to support research projects is the difference between the return a private investor would demand and the actual return for the funding authority.

Introduction

According to the staff working paper accompanying the 2018 annual competition report that was published on 15 July 2019, 95% of all State aid measures supporting R&D have been implemented on the basis of the GBER.[1] Indeed, since 2014 just seven measures have been notified to the Commission by Member States in the field of R&D. Therefore, when the Commission authorises anything that has to do with State aid to R&D it is newsworthy.

The recently approved measure SA.53791 is surely unique.[2] It is the first notified methodology on the calculation of the gross grant equivalent [GGE] of State aid contained in “repayable advances”. It must also be one of the very few measures that have been approved precisely within two months of its notification. The documentation was received by the Commission on 29 March 2019 and the measure was approved on 29 May 2019!

What is a “repayable advance” and when should it be used?

According to Article 2(21) of the GBER a repayable advance “means a loan for a project which is paid in one or more instalments and the conditions for the reimbursement of which depend on the outcome of the project”. Point 15(dd) of the RDI Framework contains exactly the same definition.

By granting a repayable advance instead of an outright grant, the public authority that provides the funding receives part of the revenue that the subsidised undertaking expects to generate. For the granting authority, a repayable advance mitigates the expense of supporting R&D. For the beneficiary undertaking, the repayable advance is a safer form of financing. If the project fails it does not have to pay back the money. Of course, it would prefer to receive a grant. But if the alternative is no financing or a straight loan, a repayable advance is welcome.

In general, a Member State should support a research project with a grant when the project is too risky and unlikely to be commercially viable without the aid. At the other end of the spectrum, a commercially viable project with normal risk [normal is what the market typically bears] should not receive public funding, or at most, public funding should be in the form of a loan or capital injection at market rates. A repayable advance falls in between a grant and a loan and it is an appropriate instrument when the commercial success of the project is uncertain and the risk of failure is higher than what the market can bear.

SA.53791: Support of R&D in the development of civil aircraft

The German measure was intended to finance R&D in the experimental development of new aircraft with more than 20 seats. The fact that the notified methodology is to be used for projects in a specific sector does not detract from its usefulness as guidance or example for similar approaches that can be applied to other sectors or projects. Naturally, the particular values of the variables used in the proposed formula may have to be adjusted to reflect the actual conditions in other sectors.

The Commission considered that the granting authority would act as a private investor “(5) if the project succeeds, the investor (i.e. the grantor of the repayable advance) will receive a return on investment, including additional royalties if the project exceeds the sale forecasts. The investor also normally receives interest on the outstanding amount (i.e. amount of repayable advance not yet repaid).”

The return that a private investor would demand for the various risks it would encounter established a benchmark for determining the GGE of the aid. Any shortfall from that benchmark would be equivalent to the amount of aid embedded in the repayable advance.

Any R&D project bears at least two risks: a technical risk [i.e. nothing useful is discovered or invented] and a commercial risk [i.e. the product that is eventually developed is a marketing flop or that competitors come up with a better product]. In this case, there was also a regulatory risk [i.e. failure to obtain a licence for new aircraft]. Boeing’s recent travails with the 737 Max show that the regulatory risk can be significant.

As explained in the Commission decision, “(7) the methodology […] relies on establishing the market conform return (the return that a market economy investor would require for the repayable advance) and on calculating the GGE of the aid of a repayable advance as the difference between the market conform return and the actual return of the repayable advance. In the proposed methodology, the market return reflects the R&D risk and the licensing risk, the specific market risk, the administrative costs and the risk-free rate of return.”

The explanation in paragraph 7 of the decision suggest that a funding authority has to calculate, first, the expected future revenue from the project, then discount it to its present value using an appropriate discount rate that reflected all the various risks and, finally, compare the derived amount to the actual amount of the repayable advance. The difference is the GGE of the aid.

For example, if the future share of the revenue from the project, F, is 120 and the risk-adjusted discount rate, r, is 20%, then a private investor would not want to invest more than a 100 [= 120/1.2]. The GGE in a repayable advance, A, is any excess amount over a 100 or, more abstractly,

GGE = A – F/(1+r)

However, the notified formula was more complicated. The Commission decision explained that “(8) for the application of the methodology, the starting point is the consideration that the project has only two possible outcomes depending on R&D success (base case) or failure (failure case):

  • If the R&D project fails (i.e. essential work packages cannot be finalised successfully or the project does not lead to an aircraft that can be commercialised and no aircraft is certified), the entire amount of the repayable advance will count as a grant where the GGE equals to the outstanding amount (failure case scenario).
  • If the R&D project leads to the commercialisation of aircraft(s), the repayable advance will be repaid according to a pre-agreed baseline repayment scenario (base case scenario). Actual repayments will depend on the degree of the project’s commercial success. Possibly, once the success threshold is reached, the specific agreement can include additional payments to the investor (bonus success fee).”

Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner

The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

In reality it is a bit unusual for a project to lead only to two mutually exclusive outcomes: failure or success. Even when a project falls short of its stated or pre-defined objectives, research almost always leads to unexpected findings [it is the very nature of research that some findings are unexpected]. Perhaps this possibility was ignored in the case of the German methodology because it was difficult to determine ex ante how to value unexpected findings. At any rate, research projects normally generate a range of outcomes, each with a different probability and a different amount of expected revenue. That is, Overall Revenue = p1R1 + p2R2 + … + pnRn. In such a typical situation, the sum of the probabilities of all potential, non-mutually exclusive outcomes does not have to add up to 1 [i.e. p1 + p2 + … + pn ≠ 1].

The formula notified by Germany calculated the present value of the GGE “(9) as the valuation of the probability that the R&D project fails (failure case scenario) plus the discounted value of the interest rate benefits obtained (calculated on the basis of a market conform return minus the contractual rate of return) in relation to the annual conditional loan disbursements and repayments (base case scenario)”.

It is difficult to understand the underlying logic of the definition in paragraph 9. For one thing, the definition of the GGE in paragraph 7 refers to a “difference”. Paragraph 9 refers to a sum [“plus”]. But if we unpack the actual formula which is shown below, it simply says that the

GGE = (amount forgone by funding authority in case of failure + discounted amount to be received by funding authority in case of success) – (discounted amount actually expected to be generated by the project in case of success)

This looks like the very simple formula derived above without the probabilities of success or failure.

The precise formula [in my simplified notation] was:

GGE = (A x p) + (1 – p) x ∑ (C x (F + R + M – IRR)/(1 + r)n)

where,

A = amount of repayable advance

p = probability of failure (reflecting both R&D risk and licensing risk)

(1 – p) = probability of success

C = cash flows

F = funding rate (which is the risk-free rate plus 0.25% to take account of related costs)

R = corporate risk rate

M = market risk rate

IRR = internal rate of return at the base scenario (successful outcome)

r = discount rate

The precise values of the variables in the formula would have to be determined by independent experts.

According to paragraph 10 of the decision, the applicable risk-free rate is equal to the swap rate corresponding to the currency and the maturity of the repayable advance. The length of the maturity is the time period until the revenue of the project reaches the pre-determined milestone for success.

“(14) On top of the funding costs, the proposed methodology puts forward that a market economy investor would ask the remuneration of the risk linked to the debtor’s creditworthiness.”

“(15) The corporate risk margin [R] depends on the debtor’s creditworthiness and collaterals. For that purpose, the rating of the benefiting company is used as well as its level of collateralisation or alternatively the one of the mother company if this would result in a lower rating.” “(16) The corporate risk margin is determined according to the Communication from the Commission on the calculation of reference rates and discount rates.”

The market risk rate, M, depends on several other variables such as demand, price levels, supply and the competitive environment. “(18) The proposed methodology puts forward that a market economy investor would ask remuneration for the risk relating to the sales forecasting errors.”

“(20) The market risk premium is established with reference to market credit default swap (CDS) premiums for projects/companies with comparable rating and thus comparable risk.”

According to the notified methodology, a “specific default rate or viability gap”, PD, would be “(21) determined on the basis of an empirical study of aircraft developments over the last three decades, which have a comparable R&D character.”

That study, which was submitted to the Commission, considered a total of 60 aircraft programmes, and identified their default rate simply as the ratio of the number of unsuccessful programmes over the number of successful programmes.

Then the annualized probability of default was

APD = – (1 – PD)(1/t)

where, t is the average maturity of non-successful programmes.

“(25) In order to translate the APD in a corresponding commercial annual risk spread reflecting the market risk, the proposed methodology takes the following steps:

a) Express the probability of default as an expected loss (EL). Based on the empirical analysis, the independent expert judged that the exposure at default (EAD), i.e. the remaining outstanding notional amount at the moment of project failure, is 50%.

EL = APD x EAD

b) In a repayable advance, recovery will not be achieved by enforcement of collateral or other liquid assets i.e. when the project stops, no more sales are realised and therefore the loss given default, for the remaining sales that will not be realised, is equal to 100%. Since this LGD is higher than the typical LGD on CDS (the average LGD on senior unsecured bonds is 60%)8, a corresponding adjustment of the probability of default (PD) is required for subsequent derivation of a corresponding credit rating as follows:

APDadj = EL / LGD

c) Calculate the adjusted multi-annual default probability of the specific project for which the valuation methodology is applied

PDp = 1 – (1 – APDadj)tp

where , PDp = the multi-annual default probability of the project;

APDadj = the annual default probability based on past empirical evidence, adjusted for an LGD of 60%;

tp = is the maturity of the project (i.e. the period required until the nominal amount of the repayable advance is repaid in full, under the base case).

d) Identify the corresponding credit rating by looking up the PDp in the average cumulative corporate default rates table provided by one reference credit rating agency given the project specific maturity.

e) The relevant market rate [M] corresponds to calculating the average spread over a basket of single name CDS of the corresponding maturity. That basket contains all EU companies for which a CDS is traded in the same rating category.

f) For each single name CDS, the last mid-prices at the time of the day the valuation is taken. Then a simple average over the resulting prices is taken to arrive at the CDS basket benchmark value. In case there are no traded CDS for the relevant project maturity, the traded CDS with the next greater maturity can be substituted.

g) If there are less than ten single CDS names in a given basket, the methodology cannot be applied.”

In order to estimate the GGE, it is first necessary to determine the contractual rate of return of the project which takes into account all the credit costs under the base case, the specific pre-agreed loans disbursements and repayments and the returns in case of payment of the success fees. The internal rate of return (IRR) is calculated as the discount rate that makes the net present value of all cash flows under the base case scenario equal to zero.

Then, “(27) the individual annual aid equivalents are calculated on the basis of the difference in interest rate calculated at the rate of return in line with the market remuneration for projects of similar risk [= C + M + F] minus the contractual rate of return (= IRR) in relation to the annual loans disbursements and repayments. This amount is then discounted at the applicable reference rate, the aid element reflecting the specific R&D risk is then added.”

Commission assessment

The Commission approved the methodology because it considered that “(35) these factors are what a market economy operator, operating in the normal conditions of a market economy and for a comparable transaction size, would evaluate for the determination of a fair remuneration of his investment.”

It then added that “(36) in line with recitals 102 to 104 of the Commission Notice on the Notion of State aid:

  • The Commission considers that, due to the debt nature of the financing instrument, it is correct to calculate the GGE of the aid of the repayable advance as the difference between the market conform rate and the actual return of the repayable advance.
  • The Commission considers that the IRR is an appropriate measure of the actual return of the repayable advance considering that it corresponds to the present value of the cash flows foreseen in the financial structure of the contracted instrument. The Commission notes that the applicable discount rate is set in accordance with the Communication from the Commission on the revision of the method for setting the reference and discount rates.”

On the basis of the above analysis, the Commission concluded that “the GGE of aid comprised in repayable advances and calculated according to the approved methodology will therefore be considered as a transparent form of aid in the meaning of Article 5(2)(j) of the GBER.”

—————————————————-

[1] The staff working paper makes for interesting reading. It can be accessed at:

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/publications/annual_report/2018/part2_en.pdf.

[2] The full text of the Commission decision can be accessed at:

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases1/201927/279600_2079931_131_2.pdf.

Tags

About

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Leave a Reply

Related Posts

21. Jun 2022
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
The Date on which State Aid is Deemed to be Granted Is not necessarily the Date on which the Actual Benefit Materialises - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 12

The Date on which State Aid is Deemed to be Granted Is not necessarily the Date on which the Actual Benefit Materialises

State aid is deemed to be granted even if the benefit cannot be quantified in advance and even if state resources are transferred at a future point in time. Introduction The precise date on which State aid is granted can be important such as, for example, when calculating the present value of aid granted in tranches at different points in […]
26. Apr 2022
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Member States Must Recover of their Own Initiative Illegally Granted Aid - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 3

Member States Must Recover of their Own Initiative Illegally Granted Aid

Aid granted illegal must be recovered by the granting authority without any need for a prior Commission decision ordering recovery. The amount of recovered aid may be limited to that which is in excess of what is allowed by the GBER. Introduction It is a well-established principle in the case law that a “prudent market operator” is responsible to check […]
15. Jun 2021
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides

State Aid to Group of Companies

In assessing the compatibility of State aid with the internal market, the Commission must also consider previous awards to a legally distinct but related company. In assessing the need for rescue/restructuring aid, the Commission must also consider whether the recipient is a member of a group that can provide internal funding. Introduction Paragraph 11 of the Commission’s Notice on the […]
06. Oct 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Member States Beware: Compliance with the GBER and the SME Criteria has just Become more Difficult - doors 1767564 1920

Member States Beware: Compliance with the GBER and the SME Criteria has just Become more Difficult

I am grateful to Péter Staviczky for comments on an earlier draft of this article. I am solely responsible for its contents. The European Commission retains its sole right to assess the compatibility of aid granted on the basis of the GBER. Criteria defined in national law need not be taken into account by the Commission. The SME status has […]
14. Jul 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
report

2019 Competition Report

The Annual Competition Report is a useful document, but it should provide more information on the results of the ex post evaluations and ex post monitoring. Update on Temporary Framework: Number of approved and published COVID-19 measures, as of 10 July 2020: 202* Legal basis: Article 107(2)(b): 20; Article 107(3)(b): 171; Article 107(3)(c): 17 Six Member States have implemented 11 […]
11. Jun 2020
Guest State Aid Blog by Erika Szyszczak
When State Aid Gets Political - brexit 3870554 1920

When State Aid Gets Political

We are happy to receive a guest comment on the EU – UK post-Brexit trade negotiations from Professor Emerita, Erika Szyszczak, who is a Fellow of UKTPO at the University of Sussex. This is a longer version of an earlier Blog published on the UKTPO website. Control over State aid is a stumbling block for the future of an EU […]
02. Jun 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Euromünzen

i) Investor-State Arbitration ii) Recovery of Incompatible State Aid iii) State Aid Scoreboard 2019

Member States abolish bilateral investment treaties between themselves. When the Commission orders recovery of incompatible State aid, interest has to be added to the recoverable amount for the whole period of illegality regardless of any national limitation rules. In 2018, Member States granted EUR 121 billion to industry and services, EUR 6.3 billion to agriculture and EUR 50 billion to […]
27. Apr 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
corona virus poster

Identification of Undertakings in Difficulty

A company is in difficulty if, in practice, its accumulated net losses exceed 50% of its subscribed capital, regardless of whether the subscribed capital is formally written down. The classification of a company as being in difficulty is independent of the sector in which it operates and of whether a private investor would be willing to invest in it. Temporary […]
21. Feb 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
From Waste to Energy - StateAidHub blogpost7 waste to energy

From Waste to Energy

State aid to incentivise the use of waste to produce energy must be individually notified. Introduction Waste management is an increasingly important aspect of policies aiming to prevent environmental degradation and slow down climate change. As the market for recycling expands and waste management becomes more profitable, there is also a higher risk of harm to competition by State aid. […]
10. Dec 2019
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Retroactive Application of the GBER - m

Retroactive Application of the GBER

When an aid scheme is adjusted by limiting the eligible beneficiaries, it becomes “new” aid and must be notified to the Commission. The GBER can be applied retroactively to aid that was granted before it came into force.   Introduction In July 2016, Dilly’s Wellnesshotel wrote legal history for being the first undertaking to contest the application of the General […]