Using the Correct Methodology to Calculate Public Service Compensation

Using the Correct Methodology to Calculate Public Service Compensation - stellrweb djb1whucfBY unsplash

Compensation for the extra costs of a public service obligation may include a reasonable profit that reflects the risk borne by the provider of the public service.

 

Introduction
 
The calculation of the amount of compensation for the extra costs of public service obligations can be difficult and tricky. In the absence of such calculation, aid to providers of services of general economic interest cannot be found to be compatible with the internal market. Since any compensation that exceeds the extra costs of the service – i.e. any overcompensation – is automatically incompatible State aid, it is absolutely indispensable to use methodologies that identify and prevent overcompensation.Commission decision SA.37977 on State aid to the incumbent postal operator in Spain found that there was overcompensation and, unavoidably instructed Spain to recover it.[1] The operator – “Correos” – a wholly state owned company, had received more than EUR 166 million in overcompensation in the period 2004-2010. On top of the overcompensation it also benefited from an exemption from real estate tax amounting to EUR 0.753 million and from a reduction of a tax on economic activities amounting to EUR 0.114 million. These amounts will have to be recovered too.Spain argued not only that there was no compensation, but also that the compensation was compliant with the Altmark conditions, so that it could not be classified as State aid at all. This meant that, in addition to proving the existence of overcompensation, the Commission had to demonstrate that the methodology used by Spain did not conform to the Altmark conditions. 

The Spanish methodology for calculating the public service compensation (PSC)

The methodology used by Spain for calculating the PSC is described in paragraph 28 of the Commission decision:

“STEP 1: Determining the unit revenue and costs of every product/service and every cost centre according to the cost accounting information of Correos. For any given product/service, those cost centres where the unit costs are higher than the unit revenue stand as loss-making. The other cost centres, where unit revenue is higher than unit costs, stand as profit-making.

STEP 2: For each reserved Service (RSi) assessing which cost centres are loss-making/profit-making for the delivery of that service and calculating the aggregate loss/profit for the delivery of that service (Loss/Profit RSi). The net cost for the reserved Services is calculated as the difference between the sum of Loss RSi and the sum of Profit RSi.

STEP 3: For each non-reserved service (NRSi) assessing which cost centres are loss-making for the delivery of that service and calculating the aggregate loss of these centres for the delivery of that service (Loss NRSi). The net cost for the non-reserved services is calculated as the sum of Loss NRSi.

STEP 4: The USO compensation covers the net cost of the reserved and non-reserved Services calculated according to Steps 2 and 3.”

The USO was the universal service obligation imposed on Correos, which was equivalent to the public service obligation (PSO). The so-called reserved services were closed to competition, while the non-reserved services were open to competition. The Spanish calculations showed that both reserved and non-reserved services were loss-making, so that the PSC was the sum of all losses in both categories of service. The total amount of the PSC for the period 2004-10 was EUR 955 million.

 


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner

The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

Conformity with the third Altmark condition

In order for the Commission to show that Correos obtained an advantage in the meaning of Article 107(1) TFEU it first had to demonstrate that Correos was an undertaking and that one or more of the Altmark conditions did not hold. This is because Spain had argued that Correos was loss making so that it could not be classified as an undertaking. The Commission responded that “(161) the mere fact that an entity does not pursue a profit does not necessarily mean that its operations are not of an economic nature.” (and cited the relevant case law) [It was rather disingenuous of Spain to contend that Correos was not an undertaking because it suffered losses. It was like claiming that inefficient companies do not operate on a market.]

The Commission also explained at the outset that “(163) an advantage for the purposes of Article 107(1) of the Treaty is any economic benefit which an undertaking would not have obtained under normal market conditions, i.e. in the absence of State intervention. Only the effect of the measure on the undertaking is relevant, neither the cause nor the objective of the State intervention. Whenever the financial situation of the undertaking is improved as a result of State intervention, an advantage is present.”

Since the four Altmark conditions are cumulative, it is sufficient for the Commission to find that one of them is not satisfied in order for compensation to constitute State aid. In most cases the Commission focuses on either the second condition [pre-determined parameters for the calculation of compensation] or the fourth condition [competitive selection of the provider or benchmarking of its costs]. In this case it chose to focus on the third condition which requires that the compensation does not exceed the net extra costs.

It began by noting that in its past decisions on postal measures, it found that a reasonable profit rate, measured as a return on sales, was 3.6%-4.8% when operators were exposed to limited risk or 5.4%-7.4% when operators bore significant risk. (Paragraph 167) The profit rate used in the calculation of the PSC for Correos was 7.4%, which the Commission considered to result in overcompensation. In response, the Spanish authorities advanced several counter-arguments the main of which was that the application of the third Altmark condition according to the net avoided cost [NAC] methodology prevented overcompensation and that the methodology that was actually used was in fact similar to the NAC.

The Commission disagreed. It recalled that “(172) the Altmark judgment was adopted on 29 July 2003. There is no doubt that at the moment of the adoption of that judgment, the only applicable method for the calculation of the net cost of SGEIs was the cost allocation methodology. The Altmark judgment itself refers to incurred costs and receipts which identifies without doubt the cost allocation methodology while the NAC relies essentially on the notion of avoided costs (which are by definition not incurred).” “(173) The NAC methodology was only introduced formally by the Commission, as a valid way to calculate the net cost of the USO, in Directive 2008/6 […] and the 2012 SGEI Framework (which entered into force on 31 January 2012).”

It is not obvious how the Commission reads such a limitation of the appropriate calculation methodology in the third Altmark condition. The text of the judgment is so general (“the compensation cannot exceed what is necessary to cover all or part of the costs incurred in the discharge of public service obligations, taking into account the relevant receipts and a reasonable profit for discharging those obligations”), that the only thing that is certain is that overcompensation is prohibited. The judgment did not refer to “incurred” costs and receipts. It referred to “what is necessary” and what is “relevant”. They do not seem to exclude any particular methodology, therefore the question that arises is whether the NAC methodology, correctly applied, would result in overcompensation in the meaning of the third Altmark condition. If that were the case, then it is hard to understand why this methodology is required by the Commission Framework on SGEI.

The Commission also disagreed with the Spanish view that the Spanish methodology was a valid implementation of the NAC methodology. It pointed out that the Spanish authorities in fact had acknowledged that the calculations for the USO reserved services were based on the cost allocation (CA) methodology. (Paragraph 178) Also, the Spanish methodology did not construct a counterfactual scenario of costs and revenues in the absence of a USO assignment whereby potentially loss-making operations could be identified and avoided ex ante. (Paragraph 180) Nor did that methodology take into account the impact from the discontinuation of loss-making operations (e.g. increase in demand for services that would be continued). (Paragraph 181)

 

Conformity with the fourth Altmark condition

Although Correos was not chosen through a competitive procedure, Spain claimed that Correos was compensated according to the costs of a “typical”, “well-run” and adequately provided” undertaking, as specified by the Court of Justice in the second part of the fourth Altmark condition. In support of this claim, Spain submitted a consultant’s report according to which Correos’s costs were lower than those of a hypothetical well-run postal operator.

The Commission rejected the consultant’s findings on the grounds that “(195) it has not been demonstrated that the USO providers used to establish this benchmark are themselves efficient operators. Instead, the study simply mentions that these postal operators are considered “well-run and adequately provided, because there is no evidence of any kind that would show them to be inefficient, or that would indicate that they have incentives to operate inefficiently”. This argument is however all the more difficult to accept that the set includes USO providers which have received USO compensation, and for which the Commission has already adopted decisions concluding that their costs could not be considered efficient costs.”

Then the Commission made a cryptic statement. “(197) Furthermore, the USO compensation of Correos has been defined on the basis of the Spanish methodology which according to the Spanish authorities is an implementation of the NAC methodology. This seems to contradict the letter of the fourth Altmark criterion which refers to the incurred cost of a well-run undertaking.”

I suppose that what paragraph 197 means is that the NAC methodology takes into account the own costs of the operator in the actual and the counterfactual scenario, not those of the hypothetical benchmark. But, even if this is the correct interpretation of paragraph 197, I don’t see why the use of the NAC methodology would necessarily contradict the benchmarking exercise of the fourth Altmark condition. For example, if before the assignment of the USO, undertaking A, that is assumed to be the most efficient on the market, incurs cost of 100 and earns revenue of 105 (which, say, results in a 5% profit] to provide a certain service [which corresponds to the counterfactual without the USO) and benchmarking shows that the next most efficient operator without access to subsidies would incur more than 100 to deliver the same service, then if undertaking A would bear cost 120 to fulfil the assignment, it follows that compensation of 21 (that covers the extra cost and includes profit of 5% on the extra cost of 20) satisfies simultaneously the third and fourth Altmark condition and the NAC methodology.

I also do not see how the Commission interprets the fourth Altmark condition to require that the companies that make up the benchmark must be efficient. The fourth Altmark condition only states that “the level of compensation needed must be determined on the basis of an analysis of the costs which a typical undertaking, well run and adequately provided […] so as to be able to meet the necessary public service requirements, would have incurred”. At most it seems to be saying that the aid recipient should not be worse than the average.

At any rate, the Commission rejected all Spanish claims and concluded that the compensation for Correos constituted State aid. It then proceeded to assess its compatibility with the internal market.

 

Incompatibility and non-conformity with the 2012 SGEI Framework

The Commission found (i) that the USO was a genuine SGEI, (ii) that the obligation had been assigned correctly through an official act which specified the terms of the service and the parameters for calculating the compensation, and (iii) that the 12-year duration of entrustment was not excessive (other postal operators had USO/PSOs spanning 15-year periods).

Given that the Commission had problems with the Spanish methodology in relation to its compatibility with the Altmark conditions, not surprisingly, it had problems too when it came to determining whether it prevented overcompensation. In its assessment, it refused to apply a NAC methodology because it was introduced after the aid to Correos had been granted. It insisted that the appropriate methodology was that of cost allocation (CA).

Because Spain used a relatively high rate of profit of 7.4%, the Commission found that there was overcompensation for the non-reserved USO services to the tune of EUR 317.4 million. But there was no overcompensation for the reserved USO services. (Paragraphs 255 & 256)

However, the amount of overcompensation was reduced by about EUR 151.3 million because the Spanish government had forced Correos to pay dividends. Correos did not have any commercial interest to do so since Correos was solely funded by the state and did not have to induce the state to provide funds like private companies have to keep paying dividends in order to attract investors. In addition, the dividends came out of its profit which was made mostly in relation to the non-reserved USO services. (Paragraphs 257 & 262)

In the end the amount of overcompensation was set at EUR 166.1 million. To this amount, the Commission added EUR 0.753 million in unpaid property taxes and EUR 0.114 million in unpaid taxes on economic activity. All three amounts have to be recovered by the Spanish authorities.

 

Other measures

The Commission also examined capital injections totalling EUR 48 million. It found them not to constitute State aid because Correos was profitable and Spain acted as a private investor. (Paragraphs 318-321)

Correos also received compensation for the costs it incurred in distributing election materials sent by political candidates. The Commission considered that such compensation fulfilled all of the criteria of Article 107(1) but it classified it as existing aid that would have to be assessed under a separate decision.

________________________________________________________

[1] The full text of the Commission decision can be accessed at: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases/262875/262875_2008814_446_2.pdf.

Tags

About

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Leave a Reply

Related Posts

23. Jan 2024
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Public Service Compensation and Indexation of Costs - State Aid Uncovered photos 2

Public Service Compensation and Indexation of Costs

Introduction Member States may impose public service obligations [PSO] on undertakings and compensate them for the extra costs they incur. The public service compensation [PSC] may also include reasonable profit. Naturally, the PSC may not cover costs that are not related to the PSO or the service of general economic interest [SGEI]. So, for multi-service providers, account separation is absolutely […]
29. Nov 2022
by Phedon Nicolaides
What Costs Must be Included in Compensation for Public Service Obligations? - State Aid Uncovered SM posts

What Costs Must be Included in Compensation for Public Service Obligations?

Introduction The two most difficult issues in imposing a public service obligation on a providers of a service of general economic interest is, first, the correct definition of the obligation and, second, the correct calculation of the amount of compensation that covers only the net extra cost of the service. The correct definition must take into account what the market […]
23. Aug 2022
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Compensation for the Net Cost of Public Service Obligations (Part II) - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 19

Compensation for the Net Cost of Public Service Obligations (Part II)

Public service obligations must be imposed through an act of entrustment that defines clearly the terms of the service and the duration of the obligation. The “reasonable profit” in the public service compensation should reflect the risk borne by the provider. Introduction In 2009, the Commission received several complaints concerning State aid that Italy had granted to the various shipping […]
16. Aug 2022
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Compensation for the Net Cost of Public Service Obligations (Part I) - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 19

Compensation for the Net Cost of Public Service Obligations (Part I)

Public service obligations must be imposed through an act of entrustment that defines clearly the terms of the service and the duration of the obligation. The “reasonable profit” in the public service compensation should reflect the risk borne by the provider. Introduction In 2009, the Commission received several complaints concerning State aid that Italy had granted to the various shipping […]
15. Dec 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
The Law, Economics and Art of Compensation for Public Service Obligations - post sign 1893086 1920 1

The Law, Economics and Art of Compensation for Public Service Obligations

State aid in the form of compensation for public service obligations must exclude any intangible benefits from the obligation, but may include reasonable profit. The Commission guidelines for State aid in agriculture and forestry, the block exemption regulations covering agriculture, forestry, fishery and aquaculture, and the Regulation on de minimis aid for fishery and aquaculture have been prolonged to 31 […]
08. Dec 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part II) - container 1638068 1920

A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part II)

For a service to be in the general economic interest, it must be shown to fill a gap in the market or to offer what the market fails to provide adequately. [In case you have missed part I, you can access it here.] Introduction Services of general economic interest [SGEI] are important for the functioning of European societies. However, the […]
01. Dec 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part I) - container 1638068 1920

A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part I)

For a service to be in the general economic interest, it must be shown to fill a gap in the market or to offer what the market fails to provide adequately. Introduction Services of general economic interest [SGEI] are important for the functioning of European societies. However, the granting of compensation to an undertaking for the provision of SGEI must […]
14. May 2020
Guest State Aid Blog by Wout De Cock
corona virus

Belgium and COVID-19: The European Commission Approves Several Belgian State Aid Measures

We are happy to share with you an update on the Covid-19 measures that have been approved in Belgium. Our guest auhor Wout De Cock is a PhD candidate at the Vrije Universiteit Brussel and part-time teaching assistant at the Katholieke Universiteit Leuven.* Introduction In issue 1/2020 of the European State Aid Law Quarterly, we concluded that the European Commission […]
07. Apr 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
EU Decisions Override National Decisions on Compensation for Public Service Obligations - StateAidHub blogpost14 Public Service Obligations 1

EU Decisions Override National Decisions on Compensation for Public Service Obligations

The principle of res judicata cannot be used to avoid recovery of incompatible State aid.   An update on State aid measures to counter the impact of COVID-19 As of 3 April 2020, the Commission has approved 29 measures submitted by 16 Member States. Article 107(3)(b) is the legal basis for 26 of those measures, while Article 107(2)(b) is the […]
04. Feb 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
How to Compensate for the Extra Cost of Public Service Obligations: Step-by-Step Guidance on a Complex Calculation - StateAidHub blogpost5 SGEI

How to Compensate for the Extra Cost of Public Service Obligations: Step-by-Step Guidance on a Complex Calculation

The “net avoided cost methodology” takes into account only incremental costs. Introduction The two most difficult issues in the design of State aid measures to support services of general economic interest [SGEI] are the proper definition of the public service obligation [PSO] and the identification of the “counterfactual” on the basis of which the public service compensation [PSC] is calculated. […]