A Measure is Selective if its Application is Narrower than the Scope of the Objective it Seeks to Achieve

Atomium Monument
A measure is attributed to a decision of a Member State if it is allowed but not mandated by an EU directive. A measure is selective when in practice it is open to fewer undertakings than the ones to which it can potentially apply by its own defined objectives.

Introduction
 
This article examines Commission Decision 2014/686 on a guarantee scheme for members of financial cooperatives in Belgium.  The Commission found that the measure constituted State aid that was in incompatible with the internal market. This is a very interesting case for three reasons. First, the guarantee scheme was found to constitute State aid despite elaborate argumentation by Belgium that it was not selective. Second, it is one of the few instances where the Commission has prohibited State aid in response to the financial crisis. And third, the Commission found that failure of financial cooperatives would not have a systemic effect on the rest of the economy.

 
Attribution to the state
 
The guarantee scheme was put in place in 2011. It covered paid-up capital of individual cooperative shareholders up to a limit of EUR 100,000. Belgium believed that the scheme did not involve State aid because Directives 94/19 and 2009/14 oblige Member States to establish guarantee schemes for depositors in credit institutions. Therefore, according to Belgium, the measure could not be attributed to a decision of a Member State and, for this reason, it did not satisfy all of the criteria of Article 107(1). However, unlike guarantee schemes for deposits which are compulsory, the Belgian measure was optional.The Commission replied in paragraph 99 of its Decision that the cooperative guarantee scheme was not a transposition of the deposit guarantee Directive 2009/14. The Directive imposes an obligation on Member States only with respect to deposits in credit institutions and explicitly excludes their capital [own funds]. The Belgian measure went beyond the requirements of the Directive and therefore was attributed to a decision of the Belgian state.Selectivity

Belgium also argued that the measure lacked selectivity because

  1. i) it was open to all cooperatives and
  2. ii) cooperatives were in a different legal and factual situation than normal companies. Cooperatives are owned by their members to whom they provide their services.

Belgium relied in particular on paragraph 61 of the judgment of the Court of Justice in case C-78/08, Paint Graphos, which was delivered in September 2011: “In the light of those special characteristics peculiar to cooperative societies, it must therefore be held that producers’ and workers’ cooperative societies such as those at issue in the main proceedings cannot, in principle, be regarded as being in a comparable factual and legal situation to that of commercial companies – provided, however, that they act in the economic interest of their members and their relations with members are not purely commercial but personal and individual, the members being actively involved in the running of the business and entitled to equitable distribution of the results of economic performance.”[1]


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

Moreover, Belgium pointed out that the Commission itself had found in its Decision N 256/2009 concerning restructuring aid to the Belgian insurance group Ethias that the extension of the state deposit guarantee scheme to “branch 21” products did not involve State aid even though Ethias derived an advantage.[2] “Branch 21” products are typically guaranteed interest rate products where the insurer assumes the risk of guaranteeing a minimum interest payment. In its Decision N 256/2009, the Commission noted that “(97) […] the Commission considered that the extension of the deposit insurance scheme to the insurance contracts of the “branch 21” constituted an advantage for Ethias. [However] […](98) According to the information provided by the Belgian authorities […], that scheme is open to all insurance companies established in Belgium or branches of insurance companies established in another Member State under the same conditions. (99) The Commission notes that although the extension of the scheme has benefited Ethias, the scheme is available to all market participants on equal terms. In view of the above, the Commission considers that the advantage conferred by the measure is not selective and therefore does not constitute State aid in the meaning of Article 107(1) TFEU.”

The Commission rejected the views of Belgium. It argued that the measure was not selective for a number of reasons.

First, it appeared to be open to all cooperatives, but in reality ARCO was the only beneficiary. ARCO was a cooperative that ran into trouble largely because it was the largest shareholder of Dexia, the failed Belgian bank. Not only was the guarantee scheme voluntary rather than obligatory, but also its coverage could be extended to a financial cooperative only after a decision of the Belgian state. No one else apart from ARCO applied to join the scheme.

Second, at the level of shareholders, the guarantee scheme was selective because it was limited to members – i.e. shareholders – of financial cooperatives and not to shareholders of other financial institutions.

Third, according to the Commission, the Belgian measure was “qualitatively different” from that which was examined by the Court of Justice in the Paint Graphos case. As noted above, the Court of Justice found that cooperatives were not in the same situation as other companies. In that case, Italian cooperatives were exempt from corporate taxation. The Court of Justice was asked through a request for preliminary ruling to give guidance on whether the exemption constituted State aid.

The Court considered that the exemption of cooperatives was not State aid if it could be justified by the logic of the system of corporate taxation. It could be justified by the logic of that system if the exemption resulted directly from the basic or guiding principles of the system for taxing corporate profit. This means that tax exemptions which are the result of an objective that is unrelated to the tax system cannot be justified by the logic of the system and therefore constitute State aid.

The Court found that cooperatives were different from normal companies because i) their assets were commonly held by their members and managed in the interest of those members who were at the same time the customers; ii) they did not have access to equity markets and were dependent on their own capital; and iii) they charged a lower interest on loans and made less profit margin.

Then the Court of Justice provided guidance to the referring national court to determine whether those differences justified exemption from the normal corporate tax. The Court of Justice observed that the exemption could be justified in case cooperative societies distributed all their profits to their members who were the ones liable for tax. By contrast, there could be no justification if profits from trade with third parties who were not members of the cooperative were also exempt from tax.

In addition, the Court noted that it was necessary for the tax exemption to comply with the principle of proportionality.

It is in light of this guidance in the Paint Graphos case, that the Commission stated in paragraph 103 of its Decision that it was “qualitatively different”. This is because “(103) […] the measure put in place by Belgium involves the creation of a positive benefit and not relief from a fiscal burden or from an obligation to pay a charge. As such, the standard three-part analysis which the Union courts have endorsed when examining whether a fiscal advantage or exemption from a levy is selective cannot be applied to the measure.” [part 1: what is the reference system?; part 2: is the measure in question a derogation from that system?; part 3: is the measure in question justified by the internal logic of the reference system?]

“(104) In any event, even if the Paint Graphos analysis could be applied to the measure, the latter’s specific features are such that its selective nature would remain.”

“(105) First the Commission observes that Paint Graphos refers to all producers’ and workers’ cooperatives, not to a relatively small subsector such as financial cooperatives. If, as Belgium claims, there should be special treatment for ‘genuine’ cooperatives, that special treatment should apply to all recognised cooperatives. The limited focus of the measure on financial cooperatives only is therefore sufficient in itself to establish the selective nature of the measure.”

“(107) Finally, even if the Commission were to enter into a Paint Graphos analysis as proposed by Belgium, it believes that there is no justification for providing a 100% guarantee to individual shareholders of ARCO (i.e. part (i) of the Paint Graphos analysis), whose entities were limited liability companies. Because of the nature of such companies as determined by Belgium’s general rules on company law, individual shareholders of ARCO should have been aware that they could lose their entire capital in case of a liquidation. Moreover, protecting 100% of all capital subscribed by the individual shareholders of financial cooperatives is not a proportionate measure (part (iii) of the Paint Graphos analysis) as those shareholders would be shielded from any risk, which would create an ndue advantage for the undertakings of which they are shareholders.”

It is difficult to know whether 100% protection is proportional or not, given the special characteristics of cooperatives, and how the Court understood the extent of the proportionality test.

However, the decisive element that establishes the selectivity of the Belgian guarantee scheme is outlined in paragraph 105 of the Commission Decision which is quoted above. The reasoning of the Commission is unassailable and very much reflects the reasoning of the Court of Justice in case C‑487/06 P, British Aggregates v Commission. In that case, the Court found that a British measure exempting waste aggregates from an environmental tax was selective. The Commission had accepted the British view that the exemption stemmed from the logic of the tax system which sought to penalise activities harmful to the environment. Britain had levied a tax on virgin aggregates which were products of mining and quarrying activities. The Court observed that the tax itself was selective because it had a narrower scope than its own objective which was the protection of the environment. The tax applied to some but not all mining and quarrying activities. In this case the selectivity was the result not of an exemption but of the non-application of the tax to all environmentally harmful activities. Although Member States are free to design their tax measures as they wish and tax any activity they want, they may not limit the application of a tax to such an extent that the tax itself confers an advantage to similar [i.e. competing] activities or products which are left outside the scope of its application.

Therefore, the Commission was right to conclude that if the objective of Belgium were to protect cooperatives because of their special characteristics, it should have widened the scope of its measure to cover all cooperatives and not only financial ones.

The lesson for Member States is simple but crucial. The scope of formal application of their measures must match the potential reach of the objectives that motivate those measures.

Incompatibility

The Commission found the guarantee scheme not to be compatible with the internal market primarily because it was not an appropriate measure to address systemic risk. Cooperatives were not exposed to “runs” by depositors in the same way that banks were. Cooperatives could simply restrict the exit of their members. Their members who were also the shareholders had different incentives than depositors in banks. They would be hit by their own exit. Moreover, cooperatives did not lend to the real economy [this is a debatable statement].

Interestingly, the Commission also concluded that the measure was disproportionate because it provided the wrong incentives to cooperatives. Since the guarantee scheme was voluntary, a cooperative could simply choose not to pay any guarantee fee until it encountered problems. Only at that moment it would request to be included in the guarantee scheme. In other words, the guarantee scheme would end up supporting only the worst cases rather than providing the same ex ante protection to all cooperatives.

 

 


 

[1] The text of the judgment can be accessed here:

http://curia.europa.eu/juris/document/document.jsf?text=&docid=109241&pageIndex=0&doclang=EN&mode=lst&dir=&occ=first&part=1&cid=178892

[2] The text of that Commission decision can be accessed here:

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases/231123/231123_1132838_112_2.pdf

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Zusammenhängende Posts

14. Mai 2020
Guest State Aid Blog von Wout De Cock
corona virus

Belgium and COVID-19: The European Commission Approves Several Belgian State Aid Measures

We are happy to share with you an update on the Covid-19 measures that have been approved in Belgium. Our guest auhor Wout De Cock is a PhD candidate at the Vrije Universiteit Brussel and part-time teaching assistant at the Katholieke Universiteit Leuven.* Introduction In issue 1/2020 of the European State Aid Law Quarterly, we concluded that the European Commission […]
03. Dez 2015
Guest State Aid Blog von Emanuela Matei
forest

The Interpretation of Conflicting Norms regarding the Validity of State Aid Infolding Contracts Must Be Consistent with the Safeguard of Individual Rights Created by EU State Aid Law (C 505/14, Klausner)

The following blog post is another contributory piece by Emanuela Matei, Associate Researcher at the Centre of European Legal Studies, Bucharest. Matei holds a Juris Master in European Business Law (Lund University, June 2012), a Magister legum (Lund University, June 2010) and a BSc in Economics & Business Administration (Lund University, June 2009). We are very glad to welcome her […]
24. Sep 2015
Guest State Aid Blog von Gian Marco Galletti
steel construction

How Reasonable The Private Investor May Be Assumed To Be? Corsica Ferries France

The following article summary is a contributory piece by Gian Marco Galletti. The full piece was published in the Common Market Law Review. Galletti is working as a researcher at the Dickson Poon School of Law since 2013. He is currently working on a PhD in European law under the supervision of Prof. Andrea Biondi. He holds an LLB with […]
16. Jan 2015
Guest State Aid Blog von Emma Linklater
Lady Justice

In Brief: Case C-518/13 Eventech and Case T-1/12 France v Commission

A quick look at the two new rulings this week. This post gives a preliminary overview of the two new judgments this week (more in depth posts with analysis will be online soon!): On Wednesday 14th January the CJEU passed its ruling in the hotly awaited Eventech case (Case C-518/13), while a day later the General Court gave its word on […]
09. Jan 2015
Guest State Aid Blog von Emma Linklater
hotel pool

In Brief: Case T-58/13, Club Hotel Loutraki AE and Others v Commission (judgment of 08.01.2015)

On Thursday the 8th January the GC dismissed all four pleas in the action for annulment of the Commission Decision finding that the exclusive rights granted to operate 35 000 Video Lottery Terminals and 13 games of chance were not State aid.   The case is can be accessed here (English and French versions currently available) and the press release here.Background to the […]
09. Dez 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Surprising Interpretation of the Concept of Selectivity - A Surprising Interpretation of the Concept of Selectivity

A Surprising Interpretation of the Concept of Selectivity

Tax measures are selective when they constitute an exception or deviation from the normal or common system of taxation. In addition, the exception must be open only to a pre-defined category of undertakings. IntroductionOften, the decisive element in whether a tax measure constitutes State aid is the existence of selectivity. On 7 November 2014, the General Court ruled on two […]
11. Nov 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
calculator

Reduction of Property Taxes and Electricity Tariffs

Relief from property tax is State aid even when the user of the property is involved in defence contracts. Providing cheaper electricity to a few manufacturers cannot be considered to be an appropriate measure for regional development. Introduction This article summarises several judgments which were delivered in October 2014. They concern a tax exemption in Spain and reduction of electricity […]
02. Sep 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Tractor on a field

Compensatory Payments Can be State Aid

Article 107(1) also applies to payments that offset the damage caused by natural disasters. It is irrelevant that the compensation is partial or that competitors did not suffer similar damage. A measure can be State aid even if it is partially or wholly funded by private resources. It is sufficient that the resources come under state control. A measure is […]
04. Aug 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
invest graph

The Profitability of an Investment Must be Determined Ex Ante

Internal transfer of capital which is not used to fund new economic activities is not State aid. Injection of fresh capital to satisfy solvency and liquidity requirements still has to comply with State aid rules. A private investor always has the option of not injecting new capital and may opt instead to close down the business. A private investor always […]
22. Jul 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Electrical grid

Sale of Public Assets, SGEI and Electricity Levies

Revenue from levies on electricity users is most likely to constitute State resources. Public service obligations can be transferred from one electricity-generating company to another. Compensation for public service obligations may distinguish between controllable and uncontrollable costs. Performance benchmarking can be used as a means for inducing efficiency. Electricity levies may not directly or indirectly discriminate against imported electricity. Introduction   This is a […]