The Emerging Doctrine of Inseparability and Compensation for Public Service Obligations [T-347/09, Germany v Commission]

hands in a forest

Introduction

In the landmark judgment in Leipzig Halle, the General Court stated that infrastructure which is inseparable from economic activity is itself economic and its public funding can fall in principle within the scope of Article 107(1) TFEU. The Court of Justice has confirmed this principle. On 12 September 2013, the General Court in its judgment in case T-347/09, Germany v Commission, also relied on the concept of inseparability to determine, however, whether certain economic activities could be considered instead to be non-economic because they were inextricably linked to non-economic activities. This is the mirror image of the principle in Leipzig Halle.

The case was an appeal brought by Germany against Commission Decision NN 8/2009 concerning public land that Germany had transferred for free to environmental organisations.[1] The mission of these organisations was preservation of natural heritage and prevention of environmental pollution. They carried out primarily non-economic activities whose public funding did not constitute State aid. The Court used the concept of inseparability to determine whether other, secondary activities could also be classified as non-economic in order to establish whether the State resources they received also fell out of the scope of Article 107(1).

In addition, Germany argued that the funding of the organisations in question was not State aid because it satisfied the Altmark criteria according to which public funding of public service obligations is not State aid. The judgment is also interesting because it sheds light on the perplexing issue of how the selection of undertakings can remove any advantage they may enjoy from public funds which are put at their disposal in the process carrying out obligations imposed by the State.

Nature of the activities of the environmental organisations

The General Court began its examination of the first plea – that the environmental organisations were not undertakings – by reiterating established case law that any entity, irrespective of legal status, is an undertaking to the extent that it carries out economic activity. It then went on to explain in paragraph 29 of the judgment that “in so far as a public entity engages in an economic activity that can be dissociated from the exercise of its public powers, the entity, in respect of this activity, is as an undertaking, while if that economic activity is inseparable from the exercise of its public powers, all the activities of the entity remain activities related to the exercise of those powers”.[2]

The Court also recalled that in the case law it is not relevant whether an entity receives payment for its services. “The fact that a product or service provided by a public entity, relating to the exercise of its public powers, is provided against remuneration stipulated by law, and not determined, directly or indirectly, by that entity, is not enough by itself to qualify the activity as economic and the entity as an undertaking”. [paragraph 30]

On the basis of these principles, the Court then considered whether the German environmental organisations could be classified as undertakings. It first found that environmental protection as such is not an economic activity. “It should be noted that it is common ground that the activity of environmental protection … is exclusively social in nature and does not constitute an economic activity.” [paragraph 31] However, it also accepted the view of the Commission that such organisations could also engage in activities other than pure environmental protection.


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

The next step for the Court was to examine whether activities such as sale of timber, the issuing of hunting and fishing permits and tourism (so-called “secondary activities”) related to the “primary functions” of the environmental organisation or whether they fell outside the framework of environmental protection and would constitute activities of economic nature. [paragraph 34]

Although the environmental organisations were operating under guidelines issued by the German authorities, they were at liberty to develop revenue-generating activities on a small scale and as a secondary purpose. The German guidelines did not list exhaustively the tasks of the environmental organisations, which, as a result, enjoyed a certain discretion in determining their functions.

Germany argued that the environmental organisations had special status and that the revenue from secondary activities was reinvested in environmental tasks. However, according to the General Court, the fact that the organisations had a special status under German law was irrelevant for the purpose of characterising them or not as undertakings under EU law.

With respect to their revenue-generating activities, the Court observed that “notwithstanding the obligation to reinvest revenues, national authorities have not determined in advance the costs of secondary activities or the method for fixing them. It follows that organisations provide environmental goods and services against remuneration and freely determine the prices thereof. … In addition, it appears … that the revenue generated by secondary activities helps organisations of environmental protection to cover costs incurred for [environmental] projects, thus reducing the use of public subsidies … It is therefore right that the Commission found, in paragraph 40 of the contested decision, that the organisations of environmental protection had an interest in generating sufficient revenue to cover costs related to the management of heritage sites and/or implementation of major projects of environmental protection.” [paragraph 39]

“By their secondary activities, including timber sales and hunting and fishing permits, organisations of environmental protection directly offer products and services on the market. The sectors such as agriculture, forestry, hunting, fishing and tourism function under market conditions and involve enterprises operating in a competitive environment and seeking to make a profit. In addition, such activities have not been and are not necessarily carried out by public authorities.” [paragraph 40]

The Court also observed that although secondary activities, such as the sale of hunting permits help protect the environment, they are not directly related to that task. “Thus, by offering goods and services in competitive markets, environmental organisations pursue a different objective that is separable from the exclusively social objective of protecting the environment. The exercise of ancillary activities cannot therefore be equated with the exercise of public powers by a public authority. Contrary to the claims of the Federal Republic of Germany, supported by the French Republic, the services provided by organisations of environmental protection do not constitute an indivisible whole.” [paragraph 41] Moreover, “secondary activities do not involve either requirements of solidarity.” [paragraph 42]

Therefore the Court concluded that “organisations of environmental protection should be considered as undertakings because they engage in economic activities, notwithstanding the fact that the supply of goods or services is made without profit, since they compete with profit-seeking operators”. [paragraph 43]

The Court recognised that “certainly, environmental requirements and, if applicable, the status of organisations protecting the environment can make [their] services less competitive than comparable services provided by other operators not subject to such obligations.” However, it still considered that this “fact does not prevent the secondary activities from being considered as economic.” [paragraph 44] The implication of this conclusion is that the mere fact that a public authority imposes costly obligations on an entity is not sufficient to “convert” it to a non-economic entity and remove it from the scope of application of Article 107(1). Either it must not carry out any economic activity at all or any compensation for the costs of the obligations must satisfy the Altmark criteria.[3]

Presence of advantage and Altmark

The Court also considered whether in principle the organisations could obtain an advantage from the free transfer of land and whether in practice they actually enjoyed such an advantage, bearing in mind the other obligations that had been imposed on them.

The Court first observed that “the advantage to the organisations of environmental protection is in the provision of free land for commercial exploitation. … The beneficiaries of the measures in question are active in economic sectors such as forestry, tourism, hunting and fishing, which are competitive markets where intra-EU trade takes place. … The measures favour the organisations of environmental protection compared to other undertakings operating in the same sectors and which would invest in land in order to carry out the same economic activities. As follows from the case-law …, it is the effect on the market which is decisive for the application of competition rules in the context of State aid. Indeed, the need to take into account the requirements of the protection of the environment, … does not justify the exclusion of selective measures such as the present measure from the scope of Article 107(1) TFEU”. [paragraphs 69-70]

After establishing that environmental organisations could in principle obtain an advantage, it examined the question whether the Altmark test was satisfied and whether as a result of the specific obligations imposed by Germany, the organisations did not in practice enjoy an advantage.

When the Commission had considered whether the fourth Altmark criterion was satisfied, it concluded as follows in its own decision:[4]

“(65) Under the notified measures, the conservation organisations are selected in an open and transparent public procedure. However, the bidding process is not based on the lowest price of the services, or on the most economically advantageous offer, but rather on the qualifications of the organizations and – only for the nature conservation projects – on the environmental merits of the projects. The amount of compensation is therefore not fixed as a result of a bidding process, contrary to what the Altmark case-law requires, and the system does not ensure that the services will be provided at the least cost for the State. Even though the German authorities have assured that, in the event of two organizations presenting offers for the same project, the more economic of the two offers would be selected, this possibility seems purely theoretical (since projects will typically be different) and would in any event only cover a fraction of projects. The amount of compensation is not fixed through benchmarking, either. Therefore, the conclusion must be drawn that the fourth Altmark condition is not fulfilled, and therefore the Altmark case-law cannot be relied upon to classify the measures as non-aid.”

The Court accepted the assessment of the Commission. The Court also found that “the secondary activities … must be considered as compensation, since their revenue normally subsidises the budget of environmental organisations which they would otherwise be required to seek support in the form of donations, despite the fact that these organisations do not retain any benefits.” [paragraph 86]

The Court was of the view that the obligation to keep separate accounts for the different activities together with the other conditions imposed were not sufficient for the purpose of excluding the possibility of excessive compensation and profit. The Court stressed that the need for cross-subsidies or the fixing of low prices did not guarantee selection of the provider with lowest cost to the community. [paragraph 87]

Conclusions

As far as division between economic and non-economic activities is concerned, it is now clear that an otherwise economic activity which is inseparably linked to a non-economic activity is itself non-economic. For example, printing is an economic activity. But printing of passports is inseparable from the issuing of passports, which is an official, non-economic act.

The selection of undertakings on which the state imposes public service obligations, it must be competitive in the sense that either the cheapest or the economically most advantageous can be chosen. Keeping separate accounts, low prices or avoiding profit is not enough. This is because an undertaking can be inefficient (having high costs) and still remain in the market due to the compensation it receives from the state. This compensation is still State aid even if it merely covers its costs without enabling it to generate any profits. Competitive selection would presumably lead to the funding of only the most efficient operator and for this reason the compensation provided by the State would be the smallest possible and would not constitute an advantaged that the chosen undertaking would not be able to obtain under normal market conditions.

————————————————-

[1] The text of the judgment can be accessed at:

http://curia.europa.eu/juris/document/document.jsf?text=&docid=140921&pageIndex=0&doclang=FR&mode=req&dir=&occ=first&part=1&cid=7279785

[2] The languages of the judgment are French and German. The English translation is mine and therefore it cannot be considered to be authoritative.

[3] A third possibility, which in fact is a variation of the first, and which is well-known from the decisional practice of the Commission regarding research organisations, is that public funding of non-economic activities must be for costs which are completely separate from those of economic activities and does not affect in any way such economic activities.

[4] The text of the Commission Decision can be accessed at:

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases/229660/229660_973605_24_1.pdf

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Zusammenhängende Posts

03. Jul 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Transactions at Market Rates Can still Confer an Advantage that Constitutes State aid (PART II) - Untitled design 17

Transactions at Market Rates Can still Confer an Advantage that Constitutes State aid (PART II)

Introduction When public authorities buy goods and services for themselves, they have to pay a market price, otherwise they confer an abnormal advantage to the sellers. On 14 June 2023, the General Court, in case T‑79/21, Ryanair & Airport Marketing Services v European Commission, ruled that public authorities still confer an abnormal advantage by buying good and services that they […]
27. Jun 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Transactions at Market Rates Can still Confer an Advantage that Constitutes State aid (PART I) - Untitled design 3 1

Transactions at Market Rates Can still Confer an Advantage that Constitutes State aid (PART I)

Introduction When public authorities buy goods and services for themselves, they have to pay a market price, otherwise they confer an abnormal advantage to the sellers. On 14 June 2023, the General Court, in case T-79/21, Ryanair & Airport Marketing Services v European Commission, ruled that public authorities still confer an abnormal advantage by buying good and services that they […]
15. Dez 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The Law, Economics and Art of Compensation for Public Service Obligations - post sign 1893086 1920 1

The Law, Economics and Art of Compensation for Public Service Obligations

State aid in the form of compensation for public service obligations must exclude any intangible benefits from the obligation, but may include reasonable profit. The Commission guidelines for State aid in agriculture and forestry, the block exemption regulations covering agriculture, forestry, fishery and aquaculture, and the Regulation on de minimis aid for fishery and aquaculture have been prolonged to 31 […]
08. Dez 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part II) - container 1638068 1920

A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part II)

For a service to be in the general economic interest, it must be shown to fill a gap in the market or to offer what the market fails to provide adequately. [In case you have missed part I, you can access it here.] Introduction Services of general economic interest [SGEI] are important for the functioning of European societies. However, the […]
01. Dez 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part I) - container 1638068 1920

A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part I)

For a service to be in the general economic interest, it must be shown to fill a gap in the market or to offer what the market fails to provide adequately. Introduction Services of general economic interest [SGEI] are important for the functioning of European societies. However, the granting of compensation to an undertaking for the provision of SGEI must […]
27. Okt 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The Common European Interest and the Environmental Impact of State Aid: The Case of Nuclear Power - nuclear power plant 4535761 1920

The Common European Interest and the Environmental Impact of State Aid: The Case of Nuclear Power

I am grateful to Peter Staviczky for comments on an earlier version. The possible negative impact of State aid on the environmental is taken into account when the aid measure violates directly the relevant EU law. The Commission protects the interests of other Member States by ensuring that the negative effects of State aid are kept to the minimum possible. […]
13. Okt 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Market Economy Operator Principle: The Case of FIH - danish currency 1139103 1920

Market Economy Operator Principle: The Case of FIH

Negotiated transactions are not necessarily market conform. Update on Temporary Framework: Number of approved and published covid-19 measures, as of 9 October 2020: 295* Legal basis: Article 107(2)(b): 32; Article 107(3)(b): 248; Article 107(3)(c): 23 – Average number of measures per Member State: 10.5 – Median number of measures per Member State: 12 – Mode number of measures per Member […]
15. Sep 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Non-economic Activities and Services of General Economic Interest - environmental protection 683437 1280

Non-economic Activities and Services of General Economic Interest

Non-economic tasks and economic activities which are inseparable from those non-economic tasks are together, as a bundle, non-economic in nature. Public compensation for the extra costs of services of general economic interest [SGEI] may not cross-subsidise activities that fall outside the scope of the SGEI. Update on Temporary Framework: Number of approved and published covid-19 measures, as of 11 September […]
05. Mai 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
corona virus poster

Non-recovery of Incompatible State aid Is Costly

Legal and practical difficulties in the recovery of incompatible State aid do not constitute justifiable “absolute impossibility”. Temporary Framework On 1 May, the total number of State aid measures to combat covid-19 approved by the European Commission reached 102. Their legal basis was: Article 107(2)(b): 9; Article 107(3)(b): 86; Article 107(3)(c): 7   Introduction The 2020 Temporary Framework for State […]
09. Apr 2020
Guest State Aid Blog von Lexxion Publisher
Woman sitting by the computer

Follow Up Webinar with Phedon Nicolaides on ‚COVID-19 and State Aid Law‘ on 20 April

The European Commission is working on quickly adapting the existing State aid legal framework to address the current Covid-19 pandemic. Join us on 20th April from the comfort and safety of your (home) office to get an insider update on the Covid-19 response by State aid experts from the European Commission and national governments. ✓ Join from wherever you are – […]