A JESSICA-Funded Public-Private Partnership

construction site
Public funding of a public-private partnership for the construction and maintenance of public schools may still involve State Aid. State Aid may have an incentive effect even when it is granted to a project that has already started. The funding gap method can demonstrate the necessity and proportionality of State Aid.

Introduction
 
This article reviews Commission Decision SA.37168 concerning the construction and maintenance of public schools in Attica, Greece.[1] This case is interesting for several reasons. The project – an urban development project – is implemented through a public-private partnership, and is partly funded by JESSICA. The project developer was selected through a competitive procedure. The ultimate beneficiary is the state organisation responsible for public schools. Yet, despite the competitive selection of the developer and the likelihood that the ultimate beneficiary is not an undertaking, JESSICA funding involves State Aid. The public funding is for a project that is already started. Lastly, the necessity and proportionality of aid is secured through calculation of the minimum possible amount of aid that can raise the financial return of the project to a “fair rate of return”.Background

In Commission Decision SA.34405 on the JESSICA Holding Fund for Greece, the Greek authorities undertook to notify to the Commission urban development projects exceeding EUR 50 million. The measure which is examined in this article was notified pursuant to that previous Decision.

Greece proposes to grant a sub-commercial loan of approximately EUR 19,375,000 to an urban development project [UDP] that consists of the design, financing, construction and facility management of 12 schools in the region of Attica.

The total costs of the UDP are estimated at EUR 58,055,976, out of which EUR 42,447,6463 is considered as eligible expenditure. JESSICA funds, invested by the urban development fund [UDF] [which comes under the Holding Fund] are in the form of a sub-commercial loan, covering approximately 46% of the eligible expenditure of the UDP. JESSICA financing amounts to approximately EUR 19,375,000 and corresponds to 50% of a senior long term debt facility (LTDF) provided together with the EIB. That is, the EIB contributes an equal amount but on commercial terms. The interest rate charged by the EIB includes a risk margin plus fees which are equal to 50% of the risk margin. The UDF loan extends for up to 27 years and its fixed interest is equal to the swap rate prevailing on the date when final lending agreement for the project was signed. The JESSICA loan will be repaid in semi-annual instalments.


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

The remaining financing for the project is provided by the project developer in the form of equity amounting to EUR 9,625,457 and by Alpha Bank, which is a commercial bank. Alpha Bank extended a loan facility of EUR 9,680,518 for liquidity purposes during the construction period.

The UDP is organized in the form of a public-private partnership. The private partner, i.e. the project developer, was selected on the basis of a public tender for making the “most economically advantageous offer”. This offer was the lowest net present value (NPV) of annual payments requested by the bidders for the maintenance of the school facilities throughout the concession period. These payments constitute the revenue of the project developer in the framework of the UDP.

In return, the project developer undertook to construct the school infrastructure and manage the school facilities (e.g. technical maintenance, security, cleaning services) during the concession period of 25 years.

However, the implementation of the project was postponed due to the financial crisis in Greece and the resulting lack of liquidity in the Greek banking system. The long term financing initially committed for the project was withdrawn. This necessitated the granting of the sub-commercial loan from the JESSICA UDF.

Assessment

The Commission has found that the JESSICA funding for the UDP (provided on sub-commercial terms) puts the project developer, as well as the UDP, in a position that is “economically advantageous compared with a situation where investments into the UDP would be carried out in line with normal market conditions” [paragraph 24].

There is no doubt that the developer is an undertaking. However, the economic nature of the UDP is questionable, given that it concerns construction and maintenance of school buildings. The UDP is in the form of a special purpose vehicle with no mandate to carry out any other activities. A public school is not normally an undertaking. The school infrastructure in this project will solely be used for educational purposes, and there will be no sub-renting of school facilities. The 12 schools will be exclusive public use, will be owned by the state and therefore, will be unavailable to be used as collateral for loans by the UDP or the project developer.

Perhaps the Commission considered that, even though a public school is not an undertaking, the maintenance of a building is an economic activity. But even if this were the view of the Commission, the direct beneficiaries are schools (which are not undertakings), while the indirect beneficiary was the developer (who was of course an undertaking). Perhaps here the Commission should have made the same distinction it makes in other JEREMIE and JESSICA projects between investors/developers the funds which are in the form of special purpose vehicles.

The terms of the JESSICA loan granted by the UDF stipulate repayment of the initial UDF investment plus at least the inflation rate, taking into account that the swap rate incorporates long term inflation expectations as set by the target inflation rate of the European Central Bank of 2%. This is of course below the rate that reflects the true risk of the project. Hence, there is no doubt that the JESSICA funding involves State aid.

Incentive effect and necessity of JESSICA support

The Greek authorities argued that the JESSICA support was necessary for the UDP to go ahead, as the project would not attract the required private investment. On first sight, this appears surprising because the project developer participated voluntarily in the bidding for the project. But, the provision of long-term development finance for all new projects, including UDPs, has been made extremely difficult as a result of the recession of the Greek economy. As a result, the bank which initially supported the bid of the project developer, subsequently withdrew from financing the project. It was also pointed out that the costs of commercial financing increased significantly since the conclusion of the public tender. Margins for long term loans have increased to a level of 650 bps from around 400 bps at the time of the tender.

At the same time, the only project revenues are the payments to be received from the Greek government, which have been set by the bidding process and cannot be increased in order to accommodate the higher costs of financing.

If commercial funding were available for the project to replace JESSICA funding – with a margin of 600 bps applied to reflect market conditions (all other parameters being equal) – the IRR for the project developer would amount to only 4.27%, rendering the project unattractive for private investment.

The Commission concluded that “the contribution of the UDF in the form of senior long term debt restores – to the extent possible – the attractiveness of the project for private investment. Therefore, without the participation of the UDF in the financing of the urban development project, its implementation would have been significantly delayed or even abandoned” [paragraph 45].

Although public funding of a project that has already started is normally considered not to have an incentive effect, we see here that, because the project would have been terminated, the Commission accepted that the aid was necessary. This case reveals that an important element in determining the presence or absence of incentive effect is not just whether a project or investment is started without aid but also whether a project or investment can in principle be completed without aid.

Proportionality of aid

The Commission has found that the JESSICA financing to restore the IRR of the project developer who was selected on the basis of a competitive process is proportional. During the tender process the potential utilization of JESSICA financing was not available, so the financing structure of the project proposed in the project developer’s offer included only a commercial bank facility and EIB financing. At that stage, the project developer’s IRR corresponded to the fair rate of return (FRR). At the time of the tender, the average yield of a 10-year Greek government bond was 9.09%, which was a “significant comparator in assessing the fairness of the rate of return achieved through the tender process” [paragraph 48].

With JESSICA support the expected IRR for the project developer is raised but the investment return prospects of the project developer still remain below the level established during the tender. This is mainly attributed to the impact of the higher pricing of the EIB senior long term loan facility.

The Commission also observed that the yield of the 10-year Greek government bond in August 2013 was 10.01%, and ranged between 9.07% and 11.58% in the first eight months of 2013. “This supports the finding that the IRR of the project developer, restored as a consequence of the UDF investment, corresponds to a FRR, taking also into account that investment in government bonds did not include the considerable construction and operational risks, which were inherent to the UDP under evaluation” [paragraph 50]. This suggests that the IRR must be higher than the yield on government bonds.

There was minimal distortion to competition, because the aid covered only the project’s viability gap. The project developer could not use State Aid to cross-subsidise other projects or strengthen its market power.

 


[1] The text of the Decision can be accessed here:

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases/249603/249603_1511017_128_2.pdf

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Zusammenhängende Posts

21. Feb 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
From Waste to Energy - StateAidHub blogpost7 waste to energy

From Waste to Energy

State aid to incentivise the use of waste to produce energy must be individually notified. Introduction Waste management is an increasingly important aspect of policies aiming to prevent environmental degradation and slow down climate change. As the market for recycling expands and waste management becomes more profitable, there is also a higher risk of harm to competition by State aid. […]
09. Jan 2018
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Structural Disadvantages and Regional Aid - StateAidHub blogpost35 port concessions

Structural Disadvantages and Regional Aid

Aid that seeks to neutralise a structural disadvantage still confers an advantage. Aid that seeks to remedy market failure is selective. State aid that is compatible with the internal market must be necessary to achieve an objective of the Treaty and be capable of incentivising a change in the behaviour of the recipient undertakings.   Introduction On 13 December 2017, […]
21. Nov 2017
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
i) Transfer of State Resources, ii) Non-recovery of Incompatible Aid, iii) Primacy of Agricultural Policy over Competition Policy - 21.11.State resources State control

i) Transfer of State Resources, ii) Non-recovery of Incompatible Aid, iii) Primacy of Agricultural Policy over Competition Policy

Private resources that come under the control of a public authority become state resources. The only defence for not recovering incompatible aid is absolute impossibility. Agricultural policy objectives take precedence over those of competition policy. Introduction This article reviews a case involving transfer of state resources and a case concerning failure to recovery of incompatible State aid. It also draws […]
21. Jun 2016
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
PART I: Combining Infrastructure Aid with SGEI Aid - m 24 1

PART I: Combining Infrastructure Aid with SGEI Aid

A provider of services of general economic interest may receive both investment aid and compensation for the extra costs of public service obligations.   Introduction Governments normally support large infrastructural projects through guarantees. This is because such projects have a long life, the initial investment costs are very high and the recoupment of investment takes place over a long period […]
18. Apr 2016
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Who is Aided when a Bank is Resolved? - m 30 1

Who is Aided when a Bank is Resolved?

Bank resolution may involve State aid. However, the depositors do not normally benefit from State aid, nor do the buyers of the viable assets, if they pay a market price. Any aid normally goes to the remaining, non-performing, assets that are eventually liquidated.   Introduction The new bank resolution regime that came into force on 1 January 2016 aims to […]
09. Jan 2015
Guest State Aid Blog von Emma Linklater
hotel pool

In Brief: Case T-58/13, Club Hotel Loutraki AE and Others v Commission (judgment of 08.01.2015)

On Thursday the 8th January the GC dismissed all four pleas in the action for annulment of the Commission Decision finding that the exclusive rights granted to operate 35 000 Video Lottery Terminals and 13 games of chance were not State aid.   The case is can be accessed here (English and French versions currently available) and the press release here.Background to the […]
16. Sep 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
coins

Simultaneity of Investments by Public and Private Investors is a Necessary but not Sufficient Condition for Public Investments to be Free of State Aid

If a public authority guarantees a loan to a company that is in financial difficulty and charges a low premium, the whole loan, not just the difference between the market rate of premium and the rate actually charged, will be considered to be State aid. Simultaneous capital injection by public and private investors is not enough to eliminate State aid […]
19. Aug 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
handshake

A Textbook Case of i) How to Sell Public Assets without Passing on Incompatible State Aid to the Buyer, and ii) How to Work together with the Commission

An undertaking that has received incompatible State aid must pay it back or, if it cannot, it must be liquidated. Before a recipient of possibly incompatible State aid is liquidated, its assets can be sold off to the highest bidder. The buyer of previously subsidised assets does not benefit from State aid if i) it pays a market price and […]
14. Feb 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
coins on the table

An Assessment of the State Aid Consistency of Financial Instruments Supported by Structural and Investment Funds (Regulation 1303/2013)

Introduction Last week I reviewed the new State aid guidelines on risk finance. This week I will examine the provisions on financial instruments in the new structural and investment funds regulation. The regulation was published in the Official Journal just before Christmas. Both sets of rules have been updated on the basis of similar principles. The primary aim of both […]
12. Dez 2013
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
antique monument

Why Can the Commission Not be Consistent in its Analysis of Economic Activity and Affectation of Trade?

Introduction If you ask a national official who deals with State aid to identify the most challenging aspects of working with State aid rules, the answer is likely to be “the concept of undertaking” and the “effect on trade”. Other aspects can also be challenging, but a national official is unlikely to agonise about the transfer of state resources, the […]