A Textbook Case of i) How to Sell Public Assets without Passing on Incompatible State Aid to the Buyer, and ii) How to Work together with the Commission

handshake
An undertaking that has received incompatible State aid must pay it back or, if it cannot, it must be liquidated. Before a recipient of possibly incompatible State aid is liquidated, its assets can be sold off to the highest bidder. The buyer of previously subsidised assets does not benefit from State aid if i) it pays a market price and ii) there is no economic continuity between the new owner and the undertaking that received the aid.

Introduction
 
The case which is reviewed in this article [SA.37954, sale of assets of Larco General Mining & Metallurgical Company] is instructive for two reasons.[1] First, it shows how to carry out a sale of public assets so that the sale does not include State aid either to the undertaking or to the new owner. Second, it demonstrates how Member States can work closely with the Commission to achieve their objectives [in this case, the orderly sale of a state-owned company], even in a situation where the Commission is likely to conclude that the undertaking in question has received incompatible State aid!Background

Greece notified, for legal certainty, its plans to sell certain assets of Larco General Mining & Metallurgical Company S.A. [Larco]. Larco is specialised in the extraction and processing of minerals such as lignite and iron. Larco is one of the largest ferronickel producers in the world. On December 2013 it had 912 employees and therefore qualified as a large enterprise. At the time of the notification, 55.2% of Larco’s shares were owned by the Greek

state through the Hellenic Republic Asset Development Fund [HRADF], 33.4% by the National Bank of Greece [NBG, a private bank] and 11.4% by Public Power Corporation [PPC, the incumbent electricity producer which is also under state control through a majority shareholding].

In the context of its economic adjustment programme, Greece undertook an extensive privatisation programme. Larco was also included in that programme.

In March 2013, the Commission initiated the formal investigation procedure in relation to six State aid measures in favour of Larco. The measures appeared to constitute State aid within the meaning of Article 107(1) TFEU. The Commission expressed doubts as regards the legality of the aid, as well as the compatibility with the internal market because Larco appeared to be a company in difficulty. At the time of writing, the formal investigation procedure was not yet concluded.

The object of the decision which is examined here was the assessment of the notification concerning the sale of certain assets of Larco and placement of the remaining company in bankruptcy.

In view of a potential conclusion of the formal investigation procedure by a negative Commission decision requesting the recovery of incompatible aid, the Greek authorities requested the Commission to confirm that a recovery obligation imposed on Larco would not concern the buyer(s) of certain assets, sold through the notified sales structure.

According to the notification, the Greek state, as the main shareholder of the company, decided the following sales structure:

Tender A

It covered the Larymna smelter and the Agios Ioannis mining area. They constituted Larco’s main operating facility. Greece would initiate an open, transparent, non-discriminatory and non-conditional tender process for the sale to the highest bidder. Greece undertook to prevent other shareholders of Larco or their affiliates from participating in tender A, in order to ensure that these entities would not use the sales process as a means to continue Larco’s economic activity, while avoiding liabilities related to Larco.


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

Tender B

It covered the Agios Ioannis remaining mining rights, the Evia mining rights, the Kastoria mining rights and the Servia mining rights. The sales structure was the same as tender A [sale to highest bidder, exclusion of existing shareholders].

The two tenders were not conditional upon each other. No bidder in one tender would be obliged to participate in the other tender. If one of the tenders was unsuccessful, the other tender would proceed normally to conclusion.

However, a “shoot-out clause” was included in each of the two tenders. According to this clause, if the preferred bidder in tender A was not the same as the preferred bidder in tender B, then the preferred bidder of each of the tenders would have the right, but not the obligation, to outbid the preferred bidder in the other tender, until the highest consideration in each of the tenders was offered.

In total, 33% of Larco’s assets net book value were covered by tenders A and B, representing approximately 60% of the company’s total ore extraction capacity.

The two tenders did not include any obligation on the buyer(s) to take over any of the employees of Larco. Any transfer of employees or employment contracts associated with the tendered assets would only be governed by the applicable provisions of EU and Greek law.

After the conclusion of the two tenders and irrespective of their outcome, Larco was to be placed in bankruptcy, according to the relevant national legislation. Its remaining assets would be disposed of as part of the liquidation process by an administrator. The proceeds were to be used to cover any outstanding liabilities of Larco, including the recovery of any potentially incompatible State aid, following a relevant Commission decision.

Greek commitments

To avoid State aid to Larco or the buyer(s), the Greek authorities undertook the following commitments: i) The two tenders would be open, transparent, non-discriminatory and non-conditional, ii) the assets would be sold to the highest bidder.

To avoid economic continuity [i.e. no economic links] and, therefore, State aid to the successor of Larco and/or the shareholders of Larco, the Greek authorities committed themselves to exclude from the bidding process the owners/shareholders of Larco or any entity linked to them.

In this way, any potential incompatible State aid to Larco would have to be recovered by that company, following a relevant Commission decision, and would not concern any buyer(s) of the assets under sale.

Commission assessment

With respect to potential aid to Larco’s buyers, the Commission explained in paragraphs 42-43 of the decision that “in order to decide on whether there is State aid benefiting Larco or the buyer(s) of the assets, the Commission needs to confirm that the sale of any assets will take place at their market price.”

The Commission concluded that the sales structure would not result in State aid to Larco or its buyer(s) because the sale of assets would be effected through open, transparent, non-discriminatory and non-conditional tender processes to the highest bidders. [paragraphs 43-44]

With respect to potential aid to any successor of Larco after its privatisation, the Commission restated the principle that “the recovery obligation may be extended to a new company, to which the company in question has transferred or sold part of its assets, where that transfer or sale structure will trigger the conclusion that there is economic continuity between the two companies”[2] [paragraph 45].

More importantly, the Commission explained that, because the procedural Regulation 659/1999 does not provide for a declaration by the Commission on issues of economic continuity, “(47) thus, the present decision is a sui generis decision, in the context of the competences attributed to the Commission for State aid control, according to Article 108 TFEU, which is also the legal basis for the recovery of incompatible aid, in case of violation of Article 108(3) TFEU, as well as according to the principle of sincere cooperation, enshrined in Article 4(3) of the Treaty on the European Union.”

According to the case law [see cases C-328/99 and C-399/00, Italy and SIM 2 v Commission and the more recent case T-123/09, Ryanair v Commission] and Commission practice [see decisions concerning Olympic Airlines, Alitalia and SERNAM],[3] the assessment of economic continuity between the “old” entity and the new structures is based on a set of indicators. The following factors may be taken into consideration: the scope of the sold assets (assets and liabilities, maintenance of workforce, bundle of assets), the sale price, the identity of the buyers, the moment of the sale (after the initiation of preliminary assessment, the formal investigation procedure or the final decision) and the economic logic of the operation.

The Commission considered that the assets to be sold that were relevant for the assessment of economic continuity were the combined assets of Tenders A and B. This was because the “shoot-out” clause created the possibility that the same buyer could succeed in both tenders.

In order to avoid economic continuity, the assets to be sold under tenders A and B would have to represent only a part of the previous company or its activities. This was acknowledged by the Commission because they represented only a part of the assets and the activity of Larco [33% of Larco’s assets net book value and about 60% of the company’s total ore extraction capacity]. With respect to the employees, the tenders would not include any specific obligation to transfer employment contracts or employees to the new owner(s).

In order to avoid economic continuity, the assets under tenders A and B would have to be sold at their market price. The competitive process ensured that the bidding would reflect market prices.

With respect to the identity of buyers, the Commission accepted that the new owner(s) of the assets would not have any economic link with Larco. This ensured that they would not be liable for any recovery of incompatible State aid.

The moment of the sale must not be such as to result in a circumvention of a decision by the Commission to recover incompatible State aid. The Commission observed that Larco had already been earmarked as a state-owned company for privatisation, in the context of the Greek economic adjustment programme. In addition, the Commission considered positively that the rest of Larco would be placed in bankruptcy, where its remaining assets and activities would be disposed of, in order to service outstanding liabilities, including a potential recovery order for incompatible State aid.

In relation to the economic logic of the operation, the decisive issue was “whether the buyer(s) of the assets will employ them in the same way as the previous owner or whether it will use them to establish a different activity or strategy” [paragraph 65].

“(66) The Commission agrees with the Greek authorities that the assets sold under Tenders A and B indeed seem to have a specific usage, serving in the activities of the extraction of laterite ore and the process and production of ferronickel, currently performed by Larco. … (67) In addition, the Commission considers that the new owner(s) who will not be obliged to take over any employees or employment contracts from Larco, will have the possibility to manage their activities under different operating conditions than Larco’s and will apply their own business model. (68) Thus, the Commission concludes that the economic logic of the operation is to allow new owner(s) to use certain assets of Larco under different conditions and not to continue the strategy of Larco.”

This conclusion, however, is doubtful. It is impossible to predict what the new owners would choose to do. At most what can be said is that the new owners would not be obliged to follow Larco’s strategy. The fact that they would not buy the whole company could be an indicator that they would not have all the means at their disposal to duplicate Larco’s strategy even if they wanted to do that.

But what this decision does not explain is why non-continuation of Larco’s strategy is relevant, given that the new owners pay a market price. The new owner obtains no advantage. The company that received the State aid is broken up and, at any rate, it is not the same company because it is now fused in a different corporate structure. It is true that sometimes subsidised companies change names or subsidised assets are transferred from one legal person to another in order to avoid repayment of subsidies. In such attempts to circumvent repayment, someone derives an advantage from the subsidies. But when the new owner pays a market price, it is difficult to understand what kind of advantage it derives even if it continues the market strategy of the company it acquires.


[1] The Commission decision can be accessed at:

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases/251096/251096_1536182_139_3.pdf

[2] See T-123/09, Ryanair Ltd v European Commission, point 155.

[3] Commission Decision of 17 September 2008, State aid N 321/2008, N 322/2008 and N 323/2008 – Greece – Vente de certains actifs d’Olympic Airlines/ Olympic Airways Services; Commission decision 12 November 2008 State aid N 510/2008 – Italy – Sale of assets of Alitalia; Commission decision of 4 April 2012 SA.34547 – France – Reprise des actifs du groupe SERNAM dans le cadre de son redressement judiciaire.

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Zusammenhängende Posts

28. Sep 2021
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Faulty Sale Procedure Can Lead to Presumption of State Aid and Annulment of a State Aid Decision - stateaid39

A Faulty Sale Procedure Can Lead to Presumption of State Aid and Annulment of a State Aid Decision

A sale of public assets cannot be presumed to be free of State aid when bidders are not treated equally. Introduction When the state sells a company it owns, there is a presumption that no State aid benefits either the buyer or the company that is sold if the sale is open transparent, non-discriminatory, unconditional and the chosen buyer is […]
09. Jan 2018
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Structural Disadvantages and Regional Aid - StateAidHub blogpost35 port concessions

Structural Disadvantages and Regional Aid

Aid that seeks to neutralise a structural disadvantage still confers an advantage. Aid that seeks to remedy market failure is selective. State aid that is compatible with the internal market must be necessary to achieve an objective of the Treaty and be capable of incentivising a change in the behaviour of the recipient undertakings.   Introduction On 13 December 2017, […]
21. Nov 2017
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
i) Transfer of State Resources, ii) Non-recovery of Incompatible Aid, iii) Primacy of Agricultural Policy over Competition Policy - 21.11.State resources State control

i) Transfer of State Resources, ii) Non-recovery of Incompatible Aid, iii) Primacy of Agricultural Policy over Competition Policy

Private resources that come under the control of a public authority become state resources. The only defence for not recovering incompatible aid is absolute impossibility. Agricultural policy objectives take precedence over those of competition policy. Introduction This article reviews a case involving transfer of state resources and a case concerning failure to recovery of incompatible State aid. It also draws […]
18. Apr 2016
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Who is Aided when a Bank is Resolved? - m 30 1

Who is Aided when a Bank is Resolved?

Bank resolution may involve State aid. However, the depositors do not normally benefit from State aid, nor do the buyers of the viable assets, if they pay a market price. Any aid normally goes to the remaining, non-performing, assets that are eventually liquidated.   Introduction The new bank resolution regime that came into force on 1 January 2016 aims to […]
05. Mrz 2015
Guest State Aid Blog von Gherardo Carullo
hospital

Procedures for examining abnormally low tenders as a State aid tool? A note on Case C-568/13 Data Medical Service

A look at the Court’s ruling of 18th December 2014 and the use of abnormally low tenders in public service contracts as indicators of illegal State subsidies. This short note examines Case C-568/13 Data Medical Service on the award of public service contracts, which is particularly interesting from a State aid perspective. While stressing that there are no exclusions whatsoever – at a […]
09. Jan 2015
Guest State Aid Blog von Emma Linklater
hotel pool

In Brief: Case T-58/13, Club Hotel Loutraki AE and Others v Commission (judgment of 08.01.2015)

On Thursday the 8th January the GC dismissed all four pleas in the action for annulment of the Commission Decision finding that the exclusive rights granted to operate 35 000 Video Lottery Terminals and 13 games of chance were not State aid.   The case is can be accessed here (English and French versions currently available) and the press release here.Background to the […]
16. Sep 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
coins

Simultaneity of Investments by Public and Private Investors is a Necessary but not Sufficient Condition for Public Investments to be Free of State Aid

If a public authority guarantees a loan to a company that is in financial difficulty and charges a low premium, the whole loan, not just the difference between the market rate of premium and the rate actually charged, will be considered to be State aid. Simultaneous capital injection by public and private investors is not enough to eliminate State aid […]
22. Jul 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Electrical grid

Sale of Public Assets, SGEI and Electricity Levies

Revenue from levies on electricity users is most likely to constitute State resources. Public service obligations can be transferred from one electricity-generating company to another. Compensation for public service obligations may distinguish between controllable and uncontrollable costs. Performance benchmarking can be used as a means for inducing efficiency. Electricity levies may not directly or indirectly discriminate against imported electricity. Introduction   This is a […]
19. Jun 2014
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
construction site

A JESSICA-Funded Public-Private Partnership

Public funding of a public-private partnership for the construction and maintenance of public schools may still involve State Aid. State Aid may have an incentive effect even when it is granted to a project that has already started. The funding gap method can demonstrate the necessity and proportionality of State Aid. Introduction   This article reviews Commission Decision SA.37168 concerning the construction […]
12. Dez 2013
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
antique monument

Why Can the Commission Not be Consistent in its Analysis of Economic Activity and Affectation of Trade?

Introduction If you ask a national official who deals with State aid to identify the most challenging aspects of working with State aid rules, the answer is likely to be “the concept of undertaking” and the “effect on trade”. Other aspects can also be challenging, but a national official is unlikely to agonise about the transfer of state resources, the […]