Media Plurality in Denmark

Media Plurality in Denmark - m 10 1

State aid measures need not be open to all undertakings.

 

Introduction

On 11 October 2016, the General Court rendered its judgment in case T-167/14, TSøndagsavisen v Commission.[1] Søndagsavisen requested annulment of Commission decision SA.36366 on a measure that had been notified by Denmark. The purpose of the measure was to support production and innovation in the newspaper and magazine sector [print media].

The applicant, Søndagsavisen, is a Danish company active in the print sector. It publishes the highest-circulation free newspaper in Denmark. Søndagsavisen is funded entirely by advertising revenue. It includes 24 regional editions with a common editorial content and advertising that is tailored to each region.

In October 2013, Denmark notified to the Commission a measure to support print media. The purpose of the measure was to ensure media pluralism. Aid was provided on the following conditions:

  • The newspaper or magazine had to be independent.
  • It had to be responsible for its articles, extending to at least half of its content.
  • It had to employ at least three employees.
  • It had to be distributed nationwide.

The requirement for articles to cover at least half of the content [the “half rule”] was intended to promote media pluralism and contribute to a vigorous democratic debate.

The maximum amount of aid was capped at 35% of the total editorial costs. In November 2013, the Commission decided that the measure was compatible with the internal market.

 

The General Court found in favour of the Commission and dismissed the appeal. Consequently, the measure was confirmed to be compatible with the internal market. But this case demonstrates that compatibility with State aid rules does not necessarily mean that aid is effective in achieving its objectives. The question not asked in this case is how money by the state can lead to media pluralism and high quality newspapers. Perhaps this is not a question that should be asked in the context of State aid assessment. But one of the common assessment principles is the appropriateness of the aid measure. Hence, this uncomfortable question needs to be raised because in the past decade only a handful of aid measures have been found to be inappropriate policy instruments. Those measures concerned conversion of analogue to digital television and they were considered to be inappropriate because simple regulation would have been sufficient. But if State aid is assessed as appropriate in 99% of all cases, is appropriateness still a useful criterion?

One reasonable reply is that, in its absence, Member States would use State aid to tackle any policy problem. Indeed, it may have a deterrent effect and force Member States to re-think their State aid measures. Another reasonable answer is that there is hardly any problem that cannot be solved by public money. But if this is true, the criterion of appropriateness needs to be refined or the Commission should apply it more rigorously. The 2012 State Aid Modernisation mentioned impact assessment studies that could differentiate between policy instruments on the basis of their effectiveness at the lowest possible distortion of competition. So far, it is not obvious from published Commission decisions how the requirement for impact assessment is enforcement.

The judgment

The applicant’s first plea was that the Commission failed to open the formal investigation procedure. The General Court recalled that the Commission is required to open the formal procedure when it has serious doubts concerning the compatibility of the aid. However, the Commission enjoys a certain margin of discretion. It can discuss any difficulties with the notifying Member State and resolve them during the preliminary stage of assessing the measure.

In addition, the Court reiterated that the concept of “serious doubts” or “serious difficulties” is objective in the sense that the existence of serious doubts or difficulties is determined by the facts of the case. Evidence that the Commission should have serious doubts is the length of its investigation or the incompleteness of that investigation. It is the notifying Member State that has to allay the fears of the Commission. And, it is the applicant that has to demonstrate the existence of serious difficulties [paragraphs 18-25]. In other words, the Commission may initially have serious doubts, but additional information and clarification provided subsequently by the notifying Member State during the preliminary assessment stage may allay those doubts.

The Court then turned its attention to the question whether the investigation of the Commission was incomplete. The applicant argued that the Commission did not consider the appropriateness of the measure and in particular the fact that the aid was available only to printed media with at least half of the contents in the form of articles.

In its decision,[2] the Commission noted that while the time spent by consumers on accessing sources of information has increased during the past decade, the share accounted by printed media has in fact declined. Consumers are less willing to pay for editorial content and the profitability of printed media has decreased. According to the Commission, this was evidence of the existence of market failure. Therefore, the aid was necessary to remedy this market failure. The aid encouraged activities that would not be performed without the aid and partly offset the extra cost of high quality content which supported democratic debate. The Commission also found that the “half rule” was appropriate in order to limit the aid to high-quality newspapers and magazines.


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

It is necessary to point out that change in consumer choices are not a sign of market failure but a sign of a thriving market and a direct consequence of the competition forces that underpin market mechanisms. However, the Commission was right in that the information is non-excludable good in the sense that its use by one consumer does not prevent its use by another. However, this has always been the case with news. The difference today is the means by which news is consumed.

The applicant for its part claimed that its newspapers too, with less than half editorial content, contributed to democratic debate by disseminating information to the greatest number of citizens.

Although the General Court acknowledged that the half rule was more likely to exclude from the aid measure free newspapers which relied on advertising revenue and therefore carried more advertisements, it was nonetheless insufficient to prove that the Commission encountered serious difficulties [paragraph 46]. Denmark was free to limit its measure to those newspapers which were more likely to have sufficient editorial content of high quality [paragraphs 46-7].

Here the Court appears to equate quantity with quality. More articles do not necessarily mean more high-quality articles. Since the problem is the low readership of newspapers in comparison to internet-based sources of information, it is, first, rather doubtful that additional articles in newspapers will be sufficient to attract back readers. What readers seem to value is not just the fact that news on the internet is provided mostly for free, it is also that it is provided in a convenient format. News can be read at any place, at any time on a mobile device. Second, it will be cheaper for newspapers to fill space in order to receive the subsidy, than fill space with more expensive high-quality writing. After all, the subsidy is capped to 35% of editorial costs. This means that for every extra expenditure of 1 euro on additional articles, a newspaper would effectively incur a net cost after the subsidy of 0.65. It can make profit only if it can generate revenue exceeding 0.65. And if it can obtain the same revenue of say 0.65 by spending 0.9 instead of 1.0, then it can make a profit of 0.065 [= 0.65 – 0.9×0.65 = 0.65 – 0.585].

Not surprisingly, the applicant disputed the existence of a link between the reduction of advertising and the quality of editorial content. The General Court replied that it was not its task to examine the eligibility conditions defined by Denmark but to consider whether the Commission had encountered serious difficulties [paragraph 53]. The Court added that the measure is based on a ratio of informative content (articles) and advertising volume and the expectation that reduction in the advertising volume would lead to high-quality content that would stimulate democratic debate [paragraph 55].

The Court went on, correctly, to reject the argument of the applicant that more advertising volume and revenue enable newspapers to produce more high-quality content. In the same way that, as the applicant correctly observed, reduction of advertising content does not necessarily lead to better articles, an increase in advertising content also does not necessarily lead to better articles. The Court also pointed out that the applicant did not provide any evidence to back up its claim [paragraph 65]. This is a lesson that claims have to be supported by tangible and credible evidence.

 

The applicant then contended that the half rule was disproportionate. If the ratio were lower than 50% then the applicant would have also been eligible to receive aid. However, the General Court pointed out that the applicant’s argument was based on the false premise that the compatibility of notified aid depends on its being available to everyone. The Court agreed with the Commission that the compatibility of aid depends on what would be the market situation without the aid [paragraph 76]. In this case, because of declining revenues, newspapers would not be able to produce editorial content without the aid [paragraph 77]. The fact that, under the half rule, free print media are in practice excluded from the aid measures does not invalidate the conclusion that free media are in a situation which is not comparable to that of other print media which have problem attracting paying customers [paragraphs 78-79].

This part of the judgment indicates that Member States are free to exclude from aid measures undertakings which do not need aid because they are in a different situation or undertakings which cannot contribute to achievement of the objectives of an aid measure. Who is or is not eligible for aid depends on the objectives of the aid measure.

Then the applicant alleged that the Commission had not had examined sufficiently whether the benefits of the measure outweighed the distortions of competition it caused.

The General Court first noted that for a measure to constitute State aid it must necessarily confer a selective advantage to a company or group of companies. Accordingly, the difference in treatment between aid beneficiaries and non-recipients of aid and the resulting distortion of competition are inherent in the concept of State aid and cannot in themselves make the aid incompatible with the internal market. [Paragraph 90]

This is indeed an important consequence of aid that is often forgotten. For a measure to be classified as state aid it must necessarily distort competition. Therefore, it is intrinsic in the concept of compatibility of aid with the internal market that some distortion is unavoidable and therefore acceptable or tolerable. The distortion that makes a measure incompatible is distortion that is not necessary or can be avoided.

Indeed, the General Court added that the distortionary effects of aid may not go beyond what is necessary for the aid to attain the objectives permitted by the Treaty. [Paragraph 91]

Therefore, the fact that, some companies were excluded from the measure did not have to cause serious difficulty for the Commission so that it would be obliged to initiate the formal investigation procedure [paragraph 92]. Moreover, according to the Court, the Commission did take into account the distortions of competition. [Paragraph 93]

The applicant also claimed that the Commission failed to fully consider the distortions of competition in the advertising market. But the Court rejected this claim because the applicant failed to explain how the aid measure could distort competition in the advertising market between free newspapers and newspapers which were sold for a price. [Paragraph 95]

It is rather difficult to understand how a reduction in reliance on advertising revenue by some newspapers could be to the disadvantage of the applicant. If those newspapers carry fewer advertisements because they need to increase their editorial content, then there will be more demand for advertising space in other newspapers. This must be beneficial to the applicant.

But more importantly, the General Court considered that the alleged distortion of competition in the advertising market was the “natural” outcome of the State aid measure, which by definition distorts or threatens to distort competition by favouring certain undertakings or certain products. The Court concluded that the distortion of competition in the advertising market could not be regarded as excessive and disproportionate, something that the applicant did not claim. [Paragraph 101]

The applicant merely noted that the aid caused distortion, not disproportionate distortion. The General Court did not explain why the distortion was not disproportionate. Immediately the question arises how one can show that distortion is disproportional. Indeed there is no threshold in the case law or the decisional practice of the Commission. This is because the proportionality of distortion is proven only indirectly. I noted a few paragraphs earlier that distortion is disproportionate when it is unnecessary or can be avoided. This is not done my measuring an index of distortion on the market but by asking whether the aid measure contains features which are discriminatory or exclusionary and which are not necessary for achieving its objectives.

————————————————————

[1] The full text of the judgment (not in English) can be accessed at:

http://curia.europa.eu/juris/fiche.jsf?id=T%3B167%3B14%3BRD%3B1%3BP%3B1%3BT2014%2F0167%2FJ&pro=&lgrec=en&nat=or&oqp=&dates=&lg=&language=en&jur=C%2CT%2CF&cit=none%252CC%252CCJ%252CR%252C2008E%252C%252C%252C%252C%252C%252C%252C%252C%252C%252Ctrue%252Cfalse%252Cfalse&num=T-167%252F14&td=%3BALL&pcs=Oor&avg=&mat=or&jge=&for=&cid=1050755.

[2] The full text of the Commission decision can be accessed at:

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases/250136/250136_1733224_153_2.pdf.

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

26. Sep 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Non-imposition of Fines on Non-illegal Behaviour - Untitled design 9

Non-imposition of Fines on Non-illegal Behaviour

Introduction Advantage is any benefit that an undertaking obtains from the intervention of the state. In some situations, however, an undertaking may derive an advantage the non-intervention of the state or, more broadly, from the failure of the state to act. This would be the case where the state does not charge a fee to a user of a state […]
03. Nov 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Evaluation of EU State Aid Rules: Need for Greater Transparency - office 4249408 1920

Evaluation of EU State Aid Rules: Need for Greater Transparency

On Friday, 30 November 2020, the European Commission published a Staff Working Document [SWD(2020) 257 final] presenting and assessing the results of the evaluation of the main State aid rules of the EU. The SWD explains the aims of the State Aid Modernisation [SAM] that was launched in 2012 and summarises the findings of the Fitness Check of the GBER, […]
11. Jun 2020
Guest State Aid Blog von Erika Szyszczak
When State Aid Gets Political - brexit 3870554 1920

When State Aid Gets Political

We are happy to receive a guest comment on the EU – UK post-Brexit trade negotiations from Professor Emerita, Erika Szyszczak, who is a Fellow of UKTPO at the University of Sussex. This is a longer version of an earlier Blog published on the UKTPO website. Control over State aid is a stumbling block for the future of an EU […]
09. Jun 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
pills on money

Private Investor and Preferential Regulatory Treatment

The existence of an advantage has to be proven, not presumed just because its absence cannot be confirmed. Preferential treatment may distort competition but it is not necessarily State aid if there is no transfer of state resources. Temporary Framework: Number of approved covid-19 measures, as of 5 June 2020: 148* Legal basis: Article 107(2)(b): 13; Article 107(3)(b): 125; Article […]
05. Mai 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
corona virus poster

Non-recovery of Incompatible State aid Is Costly

Legal and practical difficulties in the recovery of incompatible State aid do not constitute justifiable “absolute impossibility”. Temporary Framework On 1 May, the total number of State aid measures to combat covid-19 approved by the European Commission reached 102. Their legal basis was: Article 107(2)(b): 9; Article 107(3)(b): 86; Article 107(3)(c): 7   Introduction The 2020 Temporary Framework for State […]
27. Apr 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
corona virus poster

Identification of Undertakings in Difficulty

A company is in difficulty if, in practice, its accumulated net losses exceed 50% of its subscribed capital, regardless of whether the subscribed capital is formally written down. The classification of a company as being in difficulty is independent of the sector in which it operates and of whether a private investor would be willing to invest in it. Temporary […]
17. Apr 2020
Guest State Aid Blog von Michail Kamperis
Corona Virus

COVID-19 Measures Adopted and State Aid Measures (Hopefully) to Be Adopted: An Update from Cyprus

We are happy to share with you an update on the Covid-19 measures that are or will be adopted in Cyprus. Our guest auhor Michail Kamperis is a lawyer and partner at the law firm of Ierotheou, Kamperis & Co. LLC Nicosia, Cyprus. * Sign up for our free news alert  Sign Up For Free   Cyprus is one of […]
09. Apr 2020
Guest State Aid Blog von Lexxion Publisher
Woman sitting by the computer

Follow Up Webinar with Phedon Nicolaides on ‚COVID-19 and State Aid Law‘ on 20 April

The European Commission is working on quickly adapting the existing State aid legal framework to address the current Covid-19 pandemic. Join us on 20th April from the comfort and safety of your (home) office to get an insider update on the Covid-19 response by State aid experts from the European Commission and national governments. ✓ Join from wherever you are – […]
23. Dez 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Preferential Electricity Tariff Is Selective, Confers an Advantage and Distorts Competition - StateAidUncovered blogpost53 Alouminion

A Preferential Electricity Tariff Is Selective, Confers an Advantage and Distorts Competition

A judicial decision on interim measures is a selective measure. The private investor test does not apply to judicial decisions on interim measures. Introduction On 11 December 2019, in case C‑332/18 P, Mytilinaios Anonymos Etairia — Omilos Epicheiriseon v European Commission, the Court of Justice probably wrote the last chapter in a long-running case concerning privileges that had been granted […]
03. Dez 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Separability of Economic from Non-economic Activities - StateAidHub blogpost50 2019 lexxion economy printing non economic Stateaid SGEI

Separability of Economic from Non-economic Activities

Activities which are inseparable from the exercise of official powers are non-economic. Introduction   Pure research whose results are widely disseminated is undoubtedly a non-economic activity. Research reports are often published on the internet. But the design and management of a research organisation’s website can be an economic activity. Plenty of private companies provide these services for a fee. Does […]