Concession Agreements Free of State Aid

Concession Agreements Free of State Aid - concessions State aid airports

Awards of concession contracts should follow a procedure which is open, transparent, non-discriminatory and unconditional. Prices may be regulated to prevent excessive prices and profits. But, the concession fee may be adjusted to enable the concessionaire to earn a sufficient return.

 

Introduction

This article examines the link between State aid and concession agreements. In decision SA.44259, the Commission considered whether concession agreements for the upgrading, operation and maintenance of 14 Greek regional airports involved State aid.[1] The concessions were granted within the context of a broader privatisation programme that Greece had implemented in response to the economic crisis.

This is an instructive case. The Commission assessed complex contractual clauses in those agreements and concluded that they did not involve State aid because the tender was competitive, transparent, non-discriminatory and unconditional. Concession agreements are often part of public measures that support infrastructure projects. Some of the agreements are found by the Commission to include State aid, in some cases the Commission cannot exclude the possibility that State aid may be involved, while in other cases, like the one that is reviewed here, the agreements are found to be free of State aid.

Concession agreements are a policy instrument that can influence the market for a long time. These agreements normally grant exclusive rights to operators of infrastructural projects and for this reason they have the potential to distort competition to a significant degree.

The Commission has provided guidance on the selection of operators of infrastructure, including concessionaires, in its Notice on the Notion of State Aid, paragraphs 90-96 and 222-224. Given the complexity and variety of selection procedures and management contracts, it cannot be presumed that just any competitive selection procedure or any concession agreement is free of State aid.

But, the problem is that the Commission is not very consistent in its own practice. Several articles that have been published on this blog during the past few months have identified unexplained or puzzling statements in Commission decisions on selection procedures and award of contracts for management of infrastructure projects. To put it differently, where the Commission finds that the specific facts of the case lead it either to find State aid or exclude the presence of State aid, it does not always take care to explain precisely the reasons that motivate the particular decision and why, although the decision may appear to deviate from the principles expounded in the Notice, it in fact conforms with those principles.

 

The very last paragraph of the Notice on the Notion of State Aid [paragraph 230] says: “The present Communication replaces any opposing statements relating to the notion of State aid included in any existing Commission Communications and Frameworks, save for statements pertaining to specific sectors and justified by their particular features.” This is the legal equivalent of having your cake and eating it at the same time. However, given the powers of the Commission to interpret the concept of aid and its exclusive competence in determining the compatibility of aid, we should perhaps accept that it is unavoidable that Commission decisions can vary from case to case and over time. But the Commission should take care to explain better, also in order for both Member States and competitors to understand the reasoning behind its decisions.

Main features of the concession contracts

The contracts for the Greek airports were notified for the purposes of legal certainty. They concerned two concession agreements covering seven regional airports each [i.e. a total of 14 regional airports]. The contracts were signed with Fraport, a consortium led by Frankfurt Airport Services. The concessions were for a period of 40 years with the option for extension for another 10 years. [The measure was adopted in the context of a broader policy of placing all of Greece’s 37 regional airports under commercial concession contracts].

The tendering process was initiated before the new EU directive on concessions came into force in April 2016. Therefore, the concession agreement was not drafted with that directive in mind. However, it complied with the EU treaty principles of openness, transparency and non-discrimination.

The tender

The concession contract was awarded on the basis of a competitive process which was implemented in distinct phases, as follows:

Phase I: Publication of invitation to submit expressions of interest.

A total of 11 expressions of interest were received, which were evaluated according to objective criteria such as technical and financial capacity and experience. Seven offers were selected and invited to the second phase.

Phase II: Request for proposal.

The assessment in this phase was carried out in two stages.

  • In Stage 1 the non-financial aspects, such as the envisaged business strategy, of each proposal were graded on a pass/fail basis.
  • In Stage 2 the financial aspects were evaluated according to a formula that required an upfront lump-sum payment and annual lump-sum and variable payments. The latter had to be calculated as a percentage of earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortisation [EBITDA].

Final bids were received from three companies. The chosen bid offered the highest concession fee which was broken down in three parts:

  • Upfront lump sum
  • Annual lump sum
  • Annual variable fee.

Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner

The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

Airport charges

The concession agreements also defined two simultaneous ceilings on the charges that the concession holder could impose on airlines and passengers.

The first ceiling concerned the maximum amount for landing, lighting, aircraft parking and passenger charges. The revenue from these charges was intended to cover operating expenses, depreciation of assets, financial costs and the concession fee. The cap on aeronautical charges was initially set at EUR 13/passenger, but would be raised to EUR 18.5/passenger a couple of years afterwards.

The second ceiling concerned the maximum rate of return that the concessionaire could earn on the capital it invested for aeronautical services. The rate was capped at 15% per year. Any surplus had to be paid to the Greek state. The maximum rate of 15% was defined on the basis of a study on rates of return at similar airports in the Mediterranean. Interestingly, a clause in the agreements allowed the caps to be raised if the concessionaire could not earn a minimum of 7.5% and cover its operational costs.

The concession contract imposed no limit on non-aeronautical charges.

Airport development fee

In addition, the proceeds from an airport development fee [ADF] were to be shared between the concessionaire and the state. The ADF was fixed at EUR 12/passenger until 2024. Then it would decrease to EUR 3/passenger. The Greek authorities would collect the fee and pay to the concessionaire its share which was set at 91.5% until 2024 and 65% afterwards.

Public services

Certain services that fell within the public remit would be provided for free by the state, such as, for example, customs and immigration control, policing, air navigation, phytosanitary control, etc.

Although, fire-fighting services normally fall within the scope of the public remit, in this case their cost would be borne by the concessionaire. In addition, the agreements imposed on the concessionaire the obligation to provide and pay for rescue and aviation security services.

 

Assessment of the measure by the Commission

The Commission referred to paragraphs 89-96 of its Notice on the Notion of State Aid where it explained that sale of a public asset after a competitive, transparent, non-discriminatory and unconditional tender would be free of State aid. By analogy, the award of a concession under the same conditions would also be free of State aid [paragraph 41 of the Commission decision].

Then the Commission explained that a tender has to fulfil the following conditions in order to be considered as competitive, transparent, non-discriminatory and unconditional [paragraphs 42-43]:

  1. Participation is open to any interested bidder.
  2. The procedure is transparent so that all bidders have equal and full information.
  3. Sufficient time is given to bidders to prepare their bids.
  4. The award criteria are clear, objective, specified in advance and applied uniformly to all bidders. In particular, any qualitative requirements should relate to the objective of the contract and the contract should be awarded to the “highest bidder”. [The latter condition is puzzling because the economically most advantageous offer is also considered as a valid award criterion and in fact it was also mentioned in this part of the decision. But perhaps in the context of this particular case, the qualitative assessment was carried out in Stage 1 of Phase II, so the selection in Stage 2 of Phase II focused exclusively on the highest price.]
  5. Only credible and binding offers are taken into account.
  6. The tender is unconditional [with the exception of requirements that expedite the process or ensure a successful conclusion to the process].

On the basis of the above criteria, the Commission found that the procedure was open, transparent, non-discriminatory and unconditional, that the contract was awarded to the highest bidder and that the conditions that were attached to the tender were non-discriminatory and objectively related to the aim of the contract.

In connection to the objectivity of the tender conditions, the Commission noted that the caps on charges, the sharing of any surpluses and the clause for raising the caps in case of a low rate of return, were justified by the need to ensure that the airports were attractive to users, while at the same time the operator was allowed to earn a sufficient return and the state was able to maximise the fee it obtained from the operator [paragraphs 61-64].

However, four important questions arise at this point. First, is the clause on the suspension of the rate cap not in fact guaranteeing a certain minimum return which constitutes an advantage in the meaning of Article 107(1)? Second, why was it necessary to guarantee a minimum return for the concessionaire? If the minimum return was thought necessary to prevent project failure, was there any penalty in the contract in case of early exit from the contract? And if there was, why was the clause on the minimum return necessary? Third, what would happen if the low return was the fault of the concessionaire, caused by cost increases due to mismanagement? Why was there no cost benchmarking foreseen for the assessment of the performance of the concessionaire in the future? [Perhaps there was but was not mentioned in the decision.] Fourth, is price regulation in the form of caps on charges in conformity with the market economy investor principle? In this respect the Commission commented that the charge caps ensured that the airports remained attractive to users and therefore maximised revenue for the concessionaire and for the state. But the private interest of any monopolist is precisely to maximise profit. There is no need to ensure that contractually. At any rate, how did the Greek government know the right level of charges? And, since the Greek government was acting as a private investor, it should have been seeking to maximise its own share of the profits.

The Commission went on to conclude its assessment with an evaluation of the costs that were to be borne by the state in the context of the public policy remit and the costs that were assigned to the operator.

It recalled the principles of the Leipzig-Halle judgment and underlined that the state was free to fund all costs which were linked to non-economic activities. It also reiterated established case law that “an advantage is present when public authorities relieve undertakings of the costs inherent to their economic activities” [paragraph 73]. [I consider this interpretation and the use of the word “inherent” to be correct, but the problem is that the case law which is cited at this point is the judgment in cases C-172/03, Heiser, paragraph 36, and C-143/99, Adria-Wien Pipeline, paragraph 38, which refer to the standard definition of “mitigate[ion] [of] charges which are normally included in the budget of an undertaking”. What is “normal” and what is “inherent” are terms that have been subject to conflicting interpretations.] The Commission found that the definition of the non-economic activities and their funding by the state were in compliance with points 34-35 of the Aviation Guidelines. It also found, on the basis of information provided by Greece, that the state bore the costs of similar activities in all other airports. Hence, there was no preferential treatment of the concessionaire by relieving it of costs that were borne by the operators of other airports [point 37 of the Aviation Guidelines].

But it went on to examine more specifically the assignment of the costs of fire-fighting, security and rescue services to the concessionaire. Here the text of the Commission decision is ambiguous in one important respect. It notes, clearly, that the concessionaire will not derive any advantage as it pays for these services from its own income. But, given the fact that point 37 of the Aviation Guidelines requires equal treatment of all airports in any given Member State, it is unclear whether other airports have to bear the same costs. The decision only says that the state pays for the costs of services under public remit in other airports [paragraph 76]. It does not say that the state does not pay for fire-fighting in all other airports. Member States are free to designate the activities and the costs that they consider as coming under the public remit, but they must do so consistently across all airports. Hence, the issue that arises is not a favourable treatment of the 14 airports in the concession contract, but the possible favourable treatment of other airports elsewhere in Greece.

At any rate, on the basis of the above assessment, the Commission concluded that the concession agreement was free of State aid.

Conclusions and lessons to be drawn

This is an instructive case of how to design a concession agreement that does not involve State aid. Six lessons may be drawn.

First, the selection procedure must be open, transparent, non-discriminatory and unconditional. Anyone who wants to participate should be able to do so.

But, second, excluding certain potential competitors is allowed as long as the eligibility criteria are objective and relate to the economic aim of the contract.

Third, conditions that affect the economic value of the contract may not be imposed.

But, fourth, price regulation that prevents exploitation of users is a regulatory act that appears not to be contrary to State aid rules.

Fifth, the aim of a concession contract should be to maximise revenue for the state.

But, sixth, the concessionaire can be allowed to earn a sufficient rate of return, otherwise the project for which the contract is awarded may fail.

————————————–

* I am grateful to Péter Staviczky for comments on an earlier draft. I am solely responsible for the views expressed here.

[1] The full text of the Commission decision can be accessed at:

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases/266255/266255_1909595_193_2.pdf.

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

18. Jul 2024
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Compliance with EU State Aid Rules - State Aid Uncovered photos 3 1

Compliance with EU State Aid Rules

On 8 July 2024, the European Court of Auditors published its Overview of the Assurance Framework and the Key Factors Contributing to Errors in 2014-2020 Cohesion Spending, (Review 3, 2024) The main findings of the ECA concerning compliance with State aid rules can be summarised in the following two tables. 1) Most frequent errors [2018-22] (% of all errors) and […]
18. Apr 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Imposition of Public Service Obligations through Extension of a Concession - hhhhhhhh

Imposition of Public Service Obligations through Extension of a Concession

Introduction It has recently been confirmed in the case law that Member States are not obliged to implement a procurement procedure when they grant State aid. This means, of course, that the public funds they provide do confer an advantage on their recipient undertakings. Compliance with public procurement procedures affects the compatibility of the aid with the internal market. Indeed, […]
06. Apr 2021
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Lease Contracts and Competitive Selection - cow 2436354 1920

Lease Contracts and Competitive Selection

Vague award criteria can be discriminatory and harm the transparency of the selection procedure. Introduction After receiving a complaint, the Commission opened a formal investigation into alleged State aid granted by the Estonian Ministry of Rural Affairs to AS Tartu Agro, a private limited company, which produced milk, meat and cereals. According to the complaint, the Ministry had granted unlawful […]
05. Dez 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Will Brexit Usher in Protectionism? - StateAid Blogpost Brexit EU Lexxion

Will Brexit Usher in Protectionism?

The Financial Times reported on Friday, 29 November 2019, that the Conservative party in the UK announced that it would establish a different state aid system to “protect British industry after Brexit”. The Prime Minister, Boris Johnson, was quoted to have said at a press conference on the same date that the new state aid system would make it “faster […]
22. Okt 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Production of Green Electricity - StateAidHub blogpost44 greenelectricity

Production of Green Electricity

Member States may reduce the amount of State aid they grant and companies may not claim they have a right to State aid. Introduction Close to 60% of all aid granted to industry and services in the EU goes to support environmental protection, energy efficiency and the generation of electricity from renewable sources of energy. However, as technology improves, the […]
01. Okt 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Enforcement of State Aid Rules by National Courts - m 2

Enforcement of State Aid Rules by National Courts

Private enforcement has increased, but damages for illegal granting of State aid have been successfully claimed in just one case. Introduction   According to the annual competition report that was published in July, Member States use the GBER to implement 96% of their new aid measures.[1] This impressive outcome should be seen in conjunction with the recent rulings of the Court […]
28. Aug 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Curious Case of Port Concessions - StateAidHub blogpost35 port concessions

A Curious Case of Port Concessions

The obligations of a concessionaire may be made less onerous in order to enable it to remain in operation. Any adjustment of the obligations takes into account the possible legal defences of the concessionaire. Introduction The Market Economy Investor Principle [MEIP] is a powerful concept. Its many variations attest to its versatility [e.g. market economy investor, operator, vendor, creditor]. It […]
28. Mai 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
What Happens when Internal Market Rules and State Aid Rules Clash? - StateAidHub blogpost21 Tax Refund

What Happens when Internal Market Rules and State Aid Rules Clash?

A tax refund may not be granted, if it constitutes non-notified State aid.   Introduction   It is a well-established principle that restrictions on internal market rights or freedoms may not be attached to a State aid measure. Indeed, current State aid rules [e.g. GBER, guidelines] explicitly exclude from their scope any aid measure which is inseparably linked to a […]
21. Mai 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
There Is No Threshold below which Economic Activities Can Be Considered to be Non-economic - StateaidHub blogpost20 Lexxion Port Economic Activities

There Is No Threshold below which Economic Activities Can Be Considered to be Non-economic

Non-economic activities have to be accounted separately from economic activities. The exercise of public tasks assigned by the state cannot protect an undertaking from State aid rules. State aid distorts competition even when it aims to remedy distortions. Introduction Ports, like other transport infrastructures, may operate under public obligations some of which may be of economic and some of non-economic […]
02. Jan 2018
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
PART II: Concessions and State Aid: Does the State Act as a Regulator or Market Operator? - marcin jozwiak 44YvpqQ595w unsplash

PART II: Concessions and State Aid: Does the State Act as a Regulator or Market Operator?

When Member States act as regulators they need not maximise revenue from the granting of concessions rights. When Member States act as regulators they must grant concession rights on the basis of procedures which are competitive, transparent, non-discriminatory and unconditional.   Part II: Public procurement principles[1] Principles for selection of concession holders The Commission examined also, in addition to the […]